BAILII is celebrating 24 years of free online access to the law! Would you consider making a contribution?
No donation is too small. If every visitor before 31 December gives just £1, it will have a significant impact on BAILII's ability to continue providing free access to the law.
Thank you very much for your support!
[Home] [Databases] [World Law] [Multidatabase Search] [Help] [Feedback] | ||
England and Wales Court of Appeal (Civil Division) Decisions |
||
You are here: BAILII >> Databases >> England and Wales Court of Appeal (Civil Division) Decisions >> Secretary of State for Health, R (on the Application of v Association of Pharmaceutical Importers & Anor [2001] EWCA Civ 1896 (8th December, 2001) URL: http://www.bailii.org/ew/cases/EWCA/Civ/2001/1896.html Cite as: [2002] Eu LR 197, [2002] UKCLR 305, [2001] EWCA Civ 1896 |
[New search] [Printable RTF version] [Help]
IN THE SUPREME COURT OF JUDICATURE
COURT OF APPEAL (CIVIL DIVISION)
ON APPEAL FROM CROWN OFFICE LIST
MR JUSTICE THOMAS
Royal Courts of Justice Strand, London, WC2A 2LL | ||
B e f o r e :
LORD JUSTICE ALDOUS
and
LORD JUSTICE WARD
____________________
THE QUEEN
And
THE SECRETARY OF STATE FOR HEALTH
Respondent Ex parte ASSOCIATION OF PHARMACEUTICAL IMPORTERS
And
DOWELHURST LIMITED
ASSOCIATION OF THE BRITISH PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRYAppellants
Party Directly Affected
Smith Bernal Reporting Limited, 190 Fleet Street
London EC4A 2AG
Tel No: 020 7421 4040, Fax No: 020 7831 8838
Official Shorthand Writers to the Court)
Mr N. Giffin and Mr J. Coppel (instructed by Solicitor to the Department of Health for the Respondents)
Mr D. Anderson QC and Miss M. Gray (instructed by CMS Cameron McKenna for the Party Directly Affected)
____________________
(AS APPROVED BY THE COURT)
Crown Copyright ©
LORD JUSTICE ALDOUS:
“The Department is prepared under the scheme to consider proposals from companies for price modulations, where the combined effect of a set of price increases and decreases from a number of products is a cost-neutral outcome. The maximum permissible price increase for any one product is 10%. The Department may wish to monitor the effects of the modulation over several years, to ensure that the cost-neutral effect is achieved for the company in question. Any discrepancies which emerge will be raised with the company concerned. Modulations will not normally be permitted on products in Selected List categories.”
(1) The restriction upon profits to which we have referred.
(2) An initial price cut of 4.5% to be delivered from 1st October 1999. Member companies retained the discretion to leave prices on particular products unchanged, or to reduce them by variable amounts provided the 4.5% reduction in cost of sales to the NHS was achieved.
(3) Following the initial price cut, remodulation could take place which might involve both reductions and increases in prices, but only up to the level which prevailed on 1st August 1999. The effect of remodulation had to be cost-neutral, that is, it must not threaten the delivery of the 4.5% cut.
(4) Until 1st January 2001 member companies could not increase prices above their 1st August 1999 levels. They remained however entitled to apply for price increases by reference to their profit targets.
(5) From 1st January 2001 companies could remodulate by increasing prices above the level which prevailed at 1st August 1999. However such price increases were restricted to 20% above the 1st August 1999 level. The Department reserved the right to withhold agreement to price increases of 10% or more in any one year.
(6) Since price modulation and the requirement of a cost-neutral outcome were not easy to predict, member companies were permitted a margin of error of 0.5% on either side of the prescribed target.
(7) Companies seeking to modulate their prices had to comply with appropriate information requirements of the Department.”
“Principles underlying modulation as an alternative to a price reduction of 4.5% on all products
21.1 As an alternative to an across the board price reduction, scheme members may modulate the list price of their PPRS products by reductions that equate to an overall level of 4.5%. Product list prices may be increased or decreased during the period 1 October 1999 to 31 December 2000, provided that they do not exceed those that prevailed on 1 August 1999. Modulation will be deemed to have occurred where:
- List prices have been reduced by a percentage other than 4.5%.
- List prices remain unchanged from those that prevailed on 30 September 1999.
21.2 Companies can remodulate at any time from 1 October 1999, provided the Department is notified 21 days in advance of the implementation of the price change. The Department will have 14 days in which to respond to modulation notifications and will only withhold agreement where it can be shown that the effect would place the delivery of the price reduction in doubt.
21.3 Companies will not be permitted to substitute discounts or contract prices already in place before 30 September 1999. Price reductions made on products where the patent or supplementary protection certificate expires after 1 July 1999 and before 1 January 2001 will not be allowed in calculations of modulations or overall adjustments made to achieve the price reduction
Modulation principles after 1 January 2001
21.4 The Department is keen to minimise interference in the conduct of companies’ commercial affairs consistent with safeguarding public expenditure. Companies are permitted to modulate the prices of products provided that the effect of the modulation is cost neutral.
21.5 From 1 January 2001 list prices may be increased to a level no greater than 20% above the level that existed on 1 August 1999 subject to the agreement of the Department. The Department will consider applications for increases of more than 20% for products with NHS sales of £100,000 or less where a medical need can be justified. The Department may withhold agreement to any price increase of 10% or more in any one year.
21.6 The prices of new products introduced after 1 October 1999 can be increased by up to 20% after 1 January 2001. Any reduction in the price of a new product cannot be used to offset price increases on other products until the new product has been on the market in the UK for two years.
21.7 Scheme members will not be permitted to use price reductions that may be necessary as a result of patent or supplementary protection certificate expiry to justify a price increase on other products. Consequently scheme members will not be allowed to include in their modulation proposals price reductions made on products where the patent or supplementary protection certificate has expired within one year before, or will expire within two years after, the proposed date for modulation. Where a competitor product enters the market within two years of patent or supplementary protection certificate expiry, the exclusion period for modulation purposes will be extended to a maximum of 2 years from the market entry of the competitor product.”
“30. S. 33 of the Health Act 1999 (under which the PPRS was made) provides that the Secretary of State can enter into schemes with an industry body for the purpose of limiting prices or profits; a manufacturer or supplier to be bound by the scheme has to consent to the scheme being applied to him. The statutory provisions include requirements for the supply of information.
31. Under s. 35, the Secretary of State is empowered to adopt a statutory scheme for limiting prices and profits, but the provisions of the statutory scheme cannot be applied to a member of the PPRS, as s. 33(7) provides that statutory schemes do not apply to members of voluntary schemes made under s. 33.
32. On 24 January 2000, the Secretary of State made The Health Services (Control of Prices of Branded Medicines) Regulations 2000 (SI 2000 No 123) imposing a 4.5% price cut in respect of branded medicines supplied to the NHS by reference to a price list published by the Department on its internet web site; other provisions enable manufacturers or suppliers to apply for a price increase. Like the PPRS it does not impose a price cut in respect of generics. However, unlike the PPRS, it contains no modulation provisions; it is an across the board measure and allows no commercial latitude. The evidence of the Department was that this omission was intended as an incentive for all suppliers and manufacturers of branded products to join the PPRS, as the statutory scheme does not apply to those who are members of the PPRS.”
“In the Department’s view, however, it would not be appropriate for the court, in effect, to rewrite the 1999 Scheme in terms which the parties would not have agreed of their own accord. It would follow that no relief ought to be granted to the Applicants even if their legal submission were held to be well-founded.”
Whether or not that statement is correct must be the first issue to be decided.
“42. ABPI and the Department both contended that the modulation provisions could not be severed; API did not address any specific argument to the contrary. It might have been important to decide whether, for the purposes of severance, because the PPRS is an agreement, the contractual test was applicable or whether, because of the nature of the PPRS, the public law test set out in cases such as Kent County Council v Kingsway Investments [1971] AC 72 and DPP v Hutchinson [1990] 2 AC 783 applied. In R v North Hertfordshire District Council ex p Cobbold [1985] 3 All ER 486, Mann J, after setting out a number of the authorities in public law, applied the test of whether a discrete part could be excised without altering the character or substance of the rest. In contract the test can be formulated as whether severing the provisions would alter entirely the scope and intention of the agreement (see the authorities cited in Chitty 28th edition at paragraph 17-189). However in the argument before me it was not suggested that there was any material difference in the private and public law tests for severance as applied in the circumstances of this case.
43. In my view whatever test is applied it is not possible to sever the modulation provisions. It is clear on the evidence that they are an integral part of the agreement made; they are an essential part of characterising it as “light touch regulation”, as they leave substantial room for free market competition. Without them, the provisions of the agreement would have been structured differently. Indeed agreement may not have been reached, as I accept that the ABPI would probably not have agreed to a 4.5% price cut if modulation had not been included. Without the modulation provisions, therefore the character and the substance of the scheme would have been fundamentally altered; the substance would have been materially changed.”
“71. … It is not and cannot be contended that the requirement that there be an overall 4.5% price cut is unlawful. Nor it seems to me could it be contended that, if the Department had merely stipulated that there was to be an overall reduction of 4.5% by each supplier and left it to each of the pharmaceutical companies, subject to rules on predatory pricing and other anti-competitive behaviour, how to achieve that, such a stipulation would have been unlawful. Allowing the members to deliver that price cut in a manner of their choosing could not, it seems to me, be unlawful, for it would simply be allowing them the commercial freedom of the market subject to the ordinary rules on anti-competitive behaviour.”
“104. … It seems to me that if the PPRS had merely imposed a 4.5% price cut and allowed the pharmaceutical companies complete commercial freedom to achieve this in the way they wished, then it is difficult to see how, in the absence of evidence that this might potentially discriminate against imports, such a provision would have been contrary to Article 28. API thus had to show that there was some potential effect of the modulation provisions that would hinder imports in a discriminatory way. The difficulty that API faced was that they advanced this case without the evidential basis to support it, for the reasons I have given.”
Conclusion