BAILII is celebrating 24 years of free online access to the law! Would you consider making a contribution?
No donation is too small. If every visitor before 31 December gives just Β£1, it will have a significant impact on BAILII's ability to continue providing free access to the law.
Thank you very much for your support!
[Home] [Databases] [World Law] [Multidatabase Search] [Help] [Feedback] | ||
England and Wales High Court (Commercial Court) Decisions |
||
You are here: BAILII >> Databases >> England and Wales High Court (Commercial Court) Decisions >> BETWS Anthracite Ltd. v DSK Anthrazit Ibbenburen GmbH [2003] EWHC 2403 (Comm) (27 October 2003) URL: http://www.bailii.org/ew/cases/EWHC/Comm/2003/2403.html Cite as: [2004] 1 All ER (Comm) 289, [2004] 1 CMLR 12, [2004] Eu LR 241, [2003] EWHC 2403 (Comm), [2004] 1 All ER 1237 |
[New search] [Printable RTF version] [Help]
QUEENS BENCH DIVISION
COMMERCIAL COURT
Strand, London, WC2A 2LL |
||
B e f o r e :
____________________
BETWS ANTHRACITE LIMITED |
Claimant |
|
- and - |
||
DSK ANTHRAZIT IBBENBUREN GMBH |
Defendant |
____________________
Mr T. Sharpe QC & Mr P. Mitchard, solicitor-advocate (instructed by Skadden, Arps, Slate, Meagher & Flom (UK) LLP) for the Defendant
Hearing dates : 24th March-2nd April 2003
____________________
Crown Copyright ©
Mr Justice Morison :
Introduction
"The complaints in question relate to the sale in 1996 and 1997 by [Sophia Jacoba] and [Preussag] of sized-anthracite subsidised in the Community. The extremely favourable prices (compared with production costs) offered by these companies on the Community market and primarily in the United Kingdom are said to have been possible only through the use of State aid paid by Germany under Decision No 3632/93/ECSC [the Commission Decision which established Community rules for State aid to the coal industry]. This aid which, according to the complaint, covers a substantial part of the companies' production costs, is said to have been used for an unauthorised purpose.
According to the complainant [Celtic], such practices lead to distortions of competition in the Community anthracite market. In addition, the same product is sold in other Member States by the companies concerned at higher prices than in the United Kingdom."
"It can be concluded from the above that the prospects for the Community sized-anthracite market are less than promising and that the market is in steep structural decline."
"with the aid of subsidies which were used indirectly for purposes not provided for in Commission Decision No 3632/93/ECSC and 96/560/ECSC of 30 April 1996 on German Aid to the coal industry in 1995 and 1996."
They wrote to Preussag accordingly and received their responses. They did not accept Preussag's arguments. In essence, the Commission found that German Aid was permitted in relation to the fines sector of the market [that is, for power generation] but was being used to subsidise the production costs across the board. It noted that
"..the accounts do not make a clear distinction between the companies' earnings and State aid. In other words, [Preussag] treat aid as part of their turnover and do not distinguish between the consumption sectors, regardless of whether they are subsidised or as Germany claims in the case of industrial and household sectors non-subsidised."
"By using the aid for the purposes described, the companies have infringed the specific conditions of [the two Decisions] with the result that the aid cannot be considered compatible with the common market. .. The Commission therefore considers that DEM 56.6 million to Preussag was used to support the production and sale of anthracite for the industrial and household sectors and that the prices charged did not cover the production costs. It is clear from the Commission's investigations, the volumes of anthracite sold and the prices charged that part of this aid - DEM 9.8 million for [Preussag] led to distortion of competition incompatible with the common market in the Community market for sized-anthracite for industry and households, in contravention of [the 1993 Decision]. [Preussag] must therefore repay those amounts to Germany. The Commission's investigations have shown that part of [the 1997] aid, namely DEM 6.8 millions for [Preussag] led to distortion of competition As the aid in 1997 was paid in anticipation of a Commission decision, Germany must require the Company to repay the sum of DEM 6.8 millions On the basis of the principle put forward by Germany that aid payments are to be limited to coal production destined for power generation and the Community steel industry, Germany undertakes to ensure that sales of sized anthracite in the industrial and household sectors will be made at prices which cover the costs of production."
Does Betws have a cause of action?
Article 87 of the Treaty establishing the European Community provides
"1. Save as otherwise provided in this Treaty, any aid granted by a Member State or through State resources in any form whatsoever which distorts or threatens to distort competition by favouring certain undertakings or the production of certain goods shall, insofar as it affects trade between Member States be incompatible with the common market."
The Article continues in subparagraphs 2 and 3 by listing the types of aid which "shall be compatible with the common market" and aid which "may be considered to be compatible with the common market". These lists are not relevant in this case.
"The Commission shall be informed, in sufficient time to enable it to submit its comments, of any plan to grant or alter aid. If it considers that any such plan is not compatible with the common market having regard to Article 87, it shall without delay initiate the procedure provided for in paragraph (2). The Member State concerned shall not put its proposed measures into effect until this procedure has resulted in a final decision. [my emphasis].
"The national court's role is to safeguard rights which individuals enjoy as a result of the direct effect of the prohibition laid down in the last sentence of Article 88.3 The court should use all appropriate devices and remedies and apply all relevant provisions of national law to implement the direct effect of this obligation place by the Treaty on Member States. A national court must, in a case within its jurisdiction, apply Community law in its entirety and protect rights which that law confers on individuals; it must therefore set aside any provisions of national law which may conflict with it, whether prior or subsequent to the Community rule. The judge may, as appropriate and in accordance with applicable rules of national law and the developing case law of the Court of Justice, grant interim relief, for example by ordering the freezing or return of monies illegally paid, and award damages to parties whose interests are harmed.
The Court of Justice has held that the full effectiveness of Community rules would be impaired and the protection of the rights which they grant would be weakened if individuals were unable to obtain redress when their rights are infringed by a breach of Community law for which a Member State can be held responsible, the principle whereby a State must be liable for loss and damage caused to individuals as a result of breaches of Community law for which the State can he held responsible is inherent in the system of the Treaty, a national court which considers, in a case concerning Community law, that the sole obstacle precluding it from granting interim relief is a rule of national law, must set aside that rule."
And at paragraph 22 of the Guidance Notice the Commission said:
"The Court of Justice has held that a national court is bound by a Commission decision addressed to a Member State under Article 88.2 where the beneficiary of the aid in question seeks to question the validity of the decision of which it had been informed in writing by the Members State concerned and where it had failed to bring an action for annulment of the decision within the time limits prescribed by Article 230 of the EC Treaty."
"measures or practices which discriminate between producers, between purchasers or between consumers, especially in prices and delivery terms or transport rates and conditions, and measures or practices which interfere with the purchaser's free choice of supplier."
This part of the article has been held by the ECJ to have direct effect: Banks 2: HJ Banks & Co Ltd v The Coal Authority and Secretary of State for Trade and Industry [20 September 2001] Case C-390/98.
Articles 14 and 15 require the Commission to carry out the tasks assigned to it by the Treaty to "take decisions, make recommendations or deliver opinions". "Decisions shall be binding in their entirety." Article 15 requires that "decisions of the Commission shall state the reasons on which they are based and shall refer to any opinions which were required to be obtained." "Where decisions are individual in character they shall become binding upon being notified to the party concerned."
Article 33 gives the right to organisations in Preussag's position to institute proceedings in the European Court of Justice against any decision of the Commission "which they consider to involve a misuse of powers affecting them." Article 60 prohibits pricing policies which are contrary to Article 4. Article 63 provides:
"if the Commission finds that discrimination is being systematically practised by purchasers, in particular under provisions governing contracts entered into by bodies dependent on a public authority, it shall make appropriate recommendations to the governments concerned.
Articles 65 and 66(7) of the ECSC Treaty are essentially the equivalent of Articles 81 and 82 of the EC Treaty [formerly, Articles 85 and 86]. Article 65.1 provided:
"All agreements between undertakings, decisions by associations of undertakings and concerted practices tending directly or indirectly to prevent, restrict or distort normal competition within the common market shall be prohibited, and in particular those tending:Article 65.4 provided that any agreement which was in breach of paragraph 1 "shall be automatically void". It further provided that the Commission was to have sole jurisdiction to rule whether any such agreement is compatible with "this Article", "subject to the right to bring actions before the Court." The ECJ has decided that neither Article 65 nor Article 66(7) has direct effect. Article 88 gives the Commission power to record a State's failure to fulfil any obligation under the Treaty in "a reasoned decision after giving the State concerned the opportunity to submit its comments .." The State has a two-month time limit to institute proceedings before the ECJ challenging the decision.a. to fix or determine prices;b. to restrict or control production, technical development or investment;c. to share markets, products, customers or sources of supply."
The pleadings
"so as to operate a predatory and discriminatory pricing policy thus distorting competition between it and the British producers of anthracite including the Claimant".
At paragraph 7 of the Claim, the pleading reads:
"By virtue of Preussag's unlawful misuse of State Aid contrary to Article 4(b) ECSC Decision 96/560 ECSC and Decision 3632/93 ECSC, the Claimant has suffered loss and damage."
"Unless it is meant by paragraph 7 that Article 4(b) ECSC and/or Decision 96/560 and/or Decision 3632/93/ECSC is/are of direct effect, which is denied, the pleading is embarrassing as there is no proper reference to any duty owed to the Claimant by the Defendant and no allegation of breach of such duty. Accordingly there is no cause of action, alternatively, there is no reasonable prospect of success."
"arises by virtue of the following:
(a) Preussag was under a duty, which it owed to the Claimant, not to distort competition between it and Claimant by misusing the State aid granted to it. This duty was imposed by Article 4(b) ECSC by Decision 96/560 and Decision 3632/93.
(b) This breach of duty is actionable at the suit of the Claimant by virtue of Decision 1999/184. Article 1 of [that Decision] provides that Preussag improperly used the aid paid to it for 1996 in breach of Decision 96/560. Article 2 of Decision 1999/184 provides that Preussag improperly used the aid paid to it for 1997 in breach of Decision 3632/93. Decision 1999/184 is of direct effect and may be relied on by the Claimant in these proceedings to establish the breach of duty owed by Preussag. The Defendant is bound as regards issues of fact and law by Decision 1999/184. [Note: the references to Decision 1999/184 are to the Commission Decision to which extensive reference has already been made].
(c) Further or alternatively, this breach of duty is actionable at the suit of the Claimant by virtue of Article 4(b) ECSC and/or Decision 96/560 and/or Decision 3632/93. These provisions may be relied on directly in these proceedings by the Claimant to allege misuse of state aid irrespective of Decision 1999/184."
The Coal Aid Code and the authorisation decision
The structure of the 'Code' is set out in Herr Schneider's helpful expert report. He is one of the three deputy Directors of the Energy Section of the German Federal Ministry of Economics and Labour. He summarises the background to the introduction of the Coal Aid Code and draws attention to the key elements of the Code relevant to this Case. He points out that paragraph 4(c) of the ECSC contains a general prohibition on State aid and that the Coal Aid Code provides an express exemption to that prohibition, as permitted by Article 95 of the Treaty. Member States are permitted to grant aid to their coal industry only where it is designed to achieve one of three specified objectives. There are restrictions on the grant of "operating aid" including a condition that "aid must entail no distortion of competition between coal users." Member States are required to submit to the Commission a detailed modernisation plan showing how the economic viability of the undertakings concerned will be improved by reducing production costs. By 30 September each year, the Member State, which intends to grant aid to their coal industry, must inform the Commission of the nature of the support and how it will achieve the objectives. At the end of September each year the State must report to the Commission as to the aid granted for the preceding coal production year and supply to the Commission all information necessary to verify compliance with the relevant criteria. If an application for aid is made and a payment has been made in advance in anticipation of authorisation but there is a refusal, then the aid must be repaid in full together with interest.
The principle behind the German coal aid regime was to subsidise the sale of steam coal to power stations to enable the German coal industry to reduce its production gradually and in an orderly manner, and to safeguard the long-term viability of the remaining coal reserves "thus ensuring so far as possible the social and economic stability of the German coal mining communities". These objectives are within the objectives provided for by the Coal Code. Prior to 1996, the way the aid worked was for the German State to make a levy on consumers of electricity and to distribute the money collected in this way to the German Power Stations which bought German produced coal. After 1996, the State paid subsidies direct to the coal producers to enable them to reduce the price for their coal to the power stations "so as to match the prices of the third world producers". The German State achieved its objective for the period after 1995 by legislation and Guidelines. The legislation was targeted at ensuring that an appropriate share of 'hard coal' was "guaranteed to be used in the production of electrical energy ..". The mining companies were entitled to use the subsidy
"only for the exclusive purpose of offsetting the difference between the average annual production costs of each mining company and the average annual price for third country coal based on the quantities of hard coal sold. If, within the framework of the supply agreements entered into with power station operators, the average proceeds achieved by a mining company exceed the average annual price for third country coal, the annual difference between the company's average production costs and its average proceeds shall be offset."
As a result of Celtic's complaint, the German subsidy regime for 1997 was jeopardised. The Commission threatened not to permit any aid to Preussag until the Celtic complaint had been identified. But after political negotiations, the Commission agreed to approve the bulk of the proposed aid for 1997 and the Commission limited their Aid Decision to a small proportion of the State Aid for 1996 and 1997. It appears that the Commission's real complaint is that Preussag took the average cost of production of the whole of the mine's output. If costs are calculated purely on a volume basis then a disproportionate weight is given to the book costs of low value fines [power station coal] because account is not taken of the commercial value of the products based on their physical properties. Instead, the Commission suggests that a system should be used whereby the cost allocation is based on "the respective contribution of [power station and domestic coal] to turnover calculated in terms of market prices" which would thus "take account of the unit value of the products and not only of volume" and would "create a more logical relationship between the unit costs, the commercial value of the products and the necessary subsidies." It is Herr Schneider's opinion that this criticism of the way the costs of production are calculated is misplaced because the system which was used had worked without complaint in the past, was in compliance with generally accepted accounting practices and "continues to be operated widely to-day." "Subsequently, the Commission decided for political reasons that the State aid had nevertheless been used improperly. However, the general view in the German Government was that this [Aid] Decision was wrong, and that remains the general view to this day." Herr Schneider is of the view that the German legislation was compliant with the Coal Aid Code; that Preussag received the aid on the basis of the German legislation and itself did nothing wrong. As a matter of fact, there is no evidence to suggest that the misuse of State aid by Preussag was anything more than using its financial muscle, energised by the subsidy, to compete in the domestic fuel market in the UK. Had Preussag been required to sell anthracite in the domestic market at the unsubsidised cost of production, it could not have competed.
The parties' arguments
(1) The Commission has exclusive jurisdiction under the coal aid code to decide whether an agreement is compatible with Article 65 and "as long as incompatibility has not been established by the Commission itself, individuals may not plead in proceedings before the national courts that an agreement is incompatible with Article 65" paragraph 17.
(2) Similarly, it is the sole province of the Commission to decide whether undertakings hold a dominant position in the market such as to infringe Community principles of free trade paragraph 18.
(3) Article 4(d) is not applicable by itself and cannot have direct effect paragraph 16.
(4) Since the Commission has sole jurisdiction to find that the provisions of Articles 65 and 66(7) have been infringed, the national courts may not entertain an action for damages in the absence of a Commission decision adopted in the exercise of that jurisdiction." paragraph 21.
(5) Decisions of the Commission are binding in their entirety [Article 14] on the national courts. However the national courts may still ask the ECJ to rule on the validity or interpretation of those Decisions paragraph 23.
"Article 4(b) of the ECSC Treaty, in so far as it concerns discrimination between producers directly confers rights on individuals which the national courts must protect."
For the purposes of a claim for discrimination there was no requirement for a prior Decision by the Commission. The court concluded that Banks' claim that they should be retrospectively exonerated from the royalty payments could not be accepted but that that conclusion was without prejudice
"to any actions which British Coal's former competitors might bring, if the conditions were met, for compensation for any damage caused to them by the competitive advantage enjoyed by British Coal and the State companies which succeeded it."
So, Mr Brealey argues, this shows that a competitor who has been damaged as a result of the use or misuse of unlawful State aid can sue for compensation for the damage caused to them by the (unlawful) competitive advantage. Preussag is responsible for the unlawfulness. It has an obligation to use the aid conferred on them properly and that obligation is owed to competitors such as Betws. A remedy against the State is not enough: the State may not be at fault; it cannot supervise everything. This case "does not give any clear guidance" as to whether Betws can sue Preussag.
"This case raises an important question of principle concerning the system of remedies established by the EEC Treaty: namely, whether a recipient of State aid which the Commission has declared unlawful may, when called upon by the national authorities to repay the aid in accordance with the Commission's decision, challenge the validity of the decision before the national courts, and before the Court of Justice on a reference from the national court under Article 177 of the Treaty, even though it failed to challenge the Commission's decision in the Court of Justice directly under Article 173 of the Treaty."
The ECJ held that although the State was the addressee of the Commission's Decision, the undertaking in receipt of the aid also had a right to challenge the lawfulness of the decision before the ECJ and that if it failed to exercise that right of challenge within the stipulated time limit then the Decision became definitive against him. Therefore, as Mr Brealey submitted, Preussag were equally definitively bound by the Decision of the Commission in this case.
Mr Brealey submitted that the 'full effectiveness' provisions of the Treaty would be infringed if Betws were not to be accorded a right to damages against Preussag and that there was an analogy to be drawn between the position in the Crehan case and Betws' case. Crehan suggested that had been a breach of Community law, Betws should be in a position to protect its rights by an appropriate claim for damages against Preussag who had "misused" the aid provided to it by Germany. Preussag may not have been the person against whom the Commission made a complaint but it was a participant in the Commission's decision. It was invited to produce evidence in relation to the complaint and to make its comments. It was circulated with a copy of the decision.
As to the SFEI case [for which see below], that was a case which was concerned with a failure by the State to notify the Commission of the grant of State Aid. It is a decision to be confined to its own facts. Here, Preussag were also at fault in the sense that they 'misused' the State aid. What the Court was dealing with was whether a recipient should be liable in damages for the failure by the State to meet its obligations when the recipient had done no wrong. In the SFEI case, the Advocate General's remarks were posited on the basis that he was concerned with the question of the legitimate expectation of the recipient that the procedures had been complied with. Even if Preussag had such a legitimate expectation, they themselves were at fault in misusing the State Aid. There is an obligation on the recipient to use the aid in accordance with its terms.
"To allow the recipient of State aid just to get away with it and wipe out competitors and then just repay the aid at a later date does not ensure the full effectiveness of the State Aid Rules."
"must the damage suffered by the undertakings competing with the undertaking that receives the aid as a result of the latter's lack of due diligence also be compensated for in accordance with the rules of national law in order to remedy the breach of the provisions of Community Law at issue?"
The Advocate General, at paragraph 77 noted that repayment of the unlawful aid might not be a wholly adequate response to a breach of prohibition of the last sentence of Article 93(3) "in particular where the aid has resulted in a loss of profits and market share for competitors". He went on to say that the State itself might also in addition to recovering the aid from the payee be subject to claims for damages brought in the national courts on the basis of Community Law by competitors who incur loss or damage as a result of measures unlawfully implementing aid. He continued:
"Contrary to SFEI's view, the Court's existing case law does not impose on recipients of aid the obligations to make good loss or damage incurred by competitors as the result of unlawful implementation. As already noted, it merely states that recovery of aid cannot be resisted on grounds of the recipient's legitimate expectations.
Moreover, I do not think that the Court should extend its case law so as to confer on competitors a remedy in damages against recipients of aid. As the French Government points out, Article 93 lays down a procedure to be followed by the Commission and the Member States. It is upon the latter that the obligation to notify aid to the Commission rests. I do not, moreover, share SFEI's view that such a remedy is necessary in order to ensure the effectiveness of the prohibition in Article 93(3). The various remedies outlined above, including where appropriate, an order for recovery and possibly an award of damages against the Member State are capable of providing an effective response to a breach of that prohibition."
Accordingly Francis Jacobs answered the question at issue
"While Community Law may make a Member State or public body which unlawfully grants aid liable in damages, it does not oblige the recipient of such aid to make good loss or damage sustained by a competitor as a result of the unlawful grant of aid, unless the receipt of such an unlawful payment in corresponding circumstances gives rise under national law to liability in damages to third parties."
In its judgment, the Court noted that the machinery for reviewing and examining State aids established by Article 93 of the Treaty "does not impose any specific obligations on the recipient of aid". First, the notification requirement and the prior prohibition on implementing planned aid laid down in Article 93(3) are directed to the Member State. Second, the Member State is also the addressee of the Decision by which the Commission finds that aid is incompatible with the common market and requests the Member State to abolish the aid within the period determined by the Commission. That being so, Community Law does not provide a sufficient basis for the recipient to incur liability where he has failed to verify that the aid received was duly notified to the Commission. That does not, however, prejudice the possible application of national law concerning non-contractual liability. If, according to national law, the acceptance by an economic operator of unlawful assistance of a nature such as to occasion damage to other economic operators may in certain circumstances cause him to incur liability, the principle of non-discrimination may lead the national court to find the recipient of aid paid in breach of Article 93(3) of the Treaty liable." Therefore, the court concluded that the recipient of aid which was unlawful because of non-notification and who did not verify notification cannot incur liability solely on the basis of Community Law.
The Decision on the cause of action issue
" not all breaches of Community Law can give rise to an action for damages against private parties, since not all provisions of Community Law impose duties or obligations on individuals. For example, a directive does not have horizontal direct effect and cannot, by itself, impose obligations on individuals. A breach of a directive is not, therefore, a wrong actionable at the suit of another. Similarly, the system for reviewing State aids established by Article 93 of the EC Treaty [new Article 88] imposes no specific obligations on the recipient of aid. Consequently, the recipient is not liable to pay damages to a competitor for failing to verify that the aid was duly notified to the Commission." [my emphasis]. The footnote reference to the highlighted passage is the SFEI case.
Mr Brealey suggested that the next edition of his book will reflect the advancement of the law as he has submitted it to be. But I think he is trying to extend the boundaries of European Law too far. There is no indication, as I read the decisions of the ECJ, that that court would favour a claim brought by a competitor against the recipient of unlawful aid. The reference in Banks II to the possibility of a claim by Banks continuing in the national court must be seen in its context. Banks had a viable claim under Article 4(b) which is of direct effect. He was suing an emanation of the State. Betws has no cause of action against Preussag on either ground. Mr Brealey's argument that the national courts of a State are under a duty to protect competitors, and competitors have rights to complain of unlawful aid against the State under article 88.3, says nothing about the right of a competitor to bring proceedings against the recipient of the aid. His argument that it is the duty of the courts to provide the injured party with an effective remedy against the State, which includes a right to obtain damages (the doctrine of effective legal protection), also does not get him home. If there were a cause of action against Preussag, I would agree with Mr Brealey that the courts would be required to provide Betws with an adequate remedy in damages, if appropriate, so as to ensure an effective remedy for a wrong. The problem for Betws is that there is no wrong in law, in my judgment. The position seems to me to be acte clair in the light of the SFEI case. And I can understand the policy reason behind that decision. The structure of the Coal Aid Code is to ensure that the Commission must determine whether there has been an infringement with regard to the granting of the aid. Such a decision is a prerequisite to a viable action. [The position would be different if there was a claim under Article 4(b) which has direct effect]. If the Commission makes a Decision directed to the State, then I can see reasons why an action against the State by an injured competitor should not be viable. But to create a Community law tort which enabled a competitor to sue the recipient of unlawful aid would be to open a potential floodgate. It is not suggested in argument that a tort, if it existed under Community Law would be restricted. How far would an entity which was indirectly affected be able to sue; for example retailers of coal. Whilst I accept, as Mr Brealey put it, that "breach is a matter for community law and then the national courts apply their own laws to determine the extent of liability" questions will arise as to the foresee ability requirement and the extent to which the wrongdoer's knowledge of the people likely to be affected is a pre-requisite. On the evidence here, Betws would not have been a 'target' of Preussag's price war; although they would be bound to be affected to some extent; and there might be a number of other producers also affected, of whom Preussag might have been wholly unaware. These issues would need to be considered by the ECJ before it created a new Community tort of the kind suggested.
(a) The Commission has unrivalled experience in the application of the Treaty's provisions and it has a specialised jurisdiction. "The need to avoid conflicting decisions of the Commission and the national courts is obvious; and, of course, the need for finality, particularly where third party rights may be affected". " if the substance of the allegation has been made and decided by the Commission, the national court will not allow it to be re-litigated." Coal Authority v HJ Banks & co Ltd [1997] EuLR 610. That decision is consistent only with the Commission's Decision being taken as a whole: facts and conclusions.
(b) It would be contrary to public policy to allow persons who have been involved in competition proceedings in Europe to deny in the English Courts the correctness of the conclusions reached by the Commission.: Iberian UK Limited v BPB Industries Plc & British Gypsum Ltd [1997] EuLR 1, per Laddie J.(c) National courts "cannot take a decision running counter to that of the Commission even if the latter's decision conflicts with a decision given by a national court of first instance." ECJ in Case C-344/98 Masterfoods [2000] ECR 1-11369.
(d) The Dutch Banks case relied upon by Mr Sharpe was confined to the proposition that a successful party has lost his right of appeal or objection to the Decision in question if he does not challenge it timeously, and as Mr Sharpe recognised, I think, does not carry him home on this point.
These principles apply both to Germany and Preussag, who had rights to challenge the Decision in the ECJ but failed to do so.
The merits of Betws' Claim
(1) Preussag's average production costs are DEM 300 per tonne which is accounted for by reason of the depths from which the product is mined: paragraph 13.
(2) Most of the anthracite production is suitable only for power generation; some 20%-30% of the output has a high commercial value (DEM 190/t) and is sold to industry and domestic households.- paragraph 15.
(3) The market for sized anthracite is geographically limited to the traditional coal mining regions of the Community in Belgium, Germany, Spain, France and the United Kingdom. German anthracite has a good reputation in the Community market and the market in the United Kingdom for deliveries from Germany "comprised the east of the country from the Humber to the south coast " paragraph 19.
(4) Preussag and Sophia Jacoba were "able to open up a market in the United Kingdom as the State-owned National Coal Board had done little prospecting for storage sites in these areas and "they offered very favourable prices." paragraph 20.
(5) After British Coal was privatised in 1994, Celtic took over several of the Welsh pits, most of which produce anthracite. Following Celtic's acquisition of open-cast mines, it embarked on a completely new policy as it decided to expand its business in England and opened a distribution centre for its products in Hull, the main British port of entry for German Anthracite - paragraph 21.
(6) In 1995 Celtic decided to sell its products in England at the same prices as in Wales, in order to capture part of the English market, which it was able to do by meeting the costs of transport paragraph 23.
(7) Preussag's prices for anthracite were, at least during the period 1996-7 systematically lower than the prices of the companies which succeeded the National Coal Board. In January 1996 the grade 'beans' was on sale on the east coast of Britain at a price of GBP 93 per tonne from Preussag and GBP 101 per tonne from Celtic. The prices in October 1997 for the same grade were GBP 94 and GBP 103.40 respectively. "By way of comparison, anthracite from China was being sold at GBP 94 in January 1996 and at GBP 102.7 in October 1997. In 1995 sized anthracite from both Preussag and Celtic was selling for GBP 105 while the same product from China was selling for GBP 94." Paragraph 24.
(8) Preussag offers major reductions on its list prices in the various Member States. Prices charged for sales in the United Kingdom in summer 1996 ranged from DEM 153 per tonne compared with pithead list prices of DEM 400 for sized anthracite by way of comparison the pithead prices for one of the comparable grades was DEM 204 for deliveries to France, DEM 265 for deliveries to Belgium and DEM 95 for deliveries to Spain. Paragraph 25
(9) Preussag were concerned about the competition from the Welsh producers as reflected in the 1995 company report and in the 1996 company report it was stated that Preussag were able to increase their market share on the home market and some foreign markets "by means of an elastic price policy". Paragraphs 27 and 28.
(10) "This policy proved effective in practice as the information available shows that the company's exports rose from 279,000 tonnes to 358,000 tonnes between 1995 and 1996, an increase of 20%. Sales in the United Kingdom apparently increased by 49% from 66,000 tonnes to 98,000 tonnes between 1995 and 1996. The corresponding increase in France and Belgium was 13% and 8% respectively. In 1997 the volumes dropped to 68,000 tonnes to zero at the beginning of 1998." paragraph 29.
(11) "This growth in exports is all the more remarkable as it took place in difficult market conditions. Firstly, there is growing competition from third countries such as Vietnam, China or Russia, the quality of whose product is wholly acceptable for the Community market." Second, the main market for sized anthracite, that is households, "is very demanding. Although consumers are loyal to their suppliers, they are attracted to cheaper, more user friendly energy sources such as natural gas or fuel oil." Paragraphs 31 and 32..
(12) Preussag's anthracite sales at prices below the cost of production was only possible because the State "keeps the company viable with State Aid." And in the relevant two years sales of anthracite showed a surplus on the profit and loss account. Paragraphs 46 & 48.
(13) Preussag could not in the long-term have maintained their price policy at prices at prices below those of the British producers of sized anthracite without the State aid. Paragraph 58. They undercut their competitors' prices: paragraph 77.
(14) It is clear from the Commission's investigations the volumes of anthracite sold and the prices charged that part of the aid [DEM 9.8 million for Preussag] led to distortion of competition incompatible with the common market in the Community Market for sized anthracite for industry and households in contravention of [the Coal Aid Code]. The [company] must therefore repay [that] sum to Germany" Paragraph 83.
(15) In relation to the aid for 1997 which was temporarily set at DEM 65 for Preussag, DEM 6.8 million "led to distortion of competition incompatible with the common market for sized anthracite for industry and households" and Germany must require Preussag to repay that sum. Paragraph 85
(16) On the basis of the principle put forward by Germany that aid payments should be limited to coal production destined for power generation and the Community steel industry, Germany undertakes to ensure that sales of sized anthracite in the industrial and household sectors will be made at prices which cover the costs of production. Paragraph 87.
"Preussag did not receive any state aid funds or subsidies in relation to the British anthracite market (nor in relation to any part of the home heating market). The fact that it received the DEM 16.6 in state aid which the European Commission later decided had been misused in 1996 and 1997 had no bearing on its commercial decision to reduce its prices." [Paragraph 98]
That paragraph conflicts with sub-paragraphs (12) and (13) above.
(1) Preussag had been importing anthracite into the British market since the mid 1970s. He says, and I accept, that the German product from Preussag's Ibbenburen mine was of particularly good quality and was especially hard [with a low ash content and medium volatility] and regarded as a reliable source of good quality fuel.
(2) The market was diminishing as users preferred the more user-friendly sources of heat [gas or oil]. Whereas quality was the governing factor in the 1990s price alone became the dominant consideration.
(3) Preussag sold its anthracite into England through German exporters [Stinnes] who in turn dealt with one particular wholesaler in England, namely British Fuels Limited, which was fully owned by British Coal from the late 1980s until British Coal was privatised in 1994.
(4) Preussag quoted base prices in sterling: £s per tonne ex Nordenham, and the price included the cost of transport by rail or canal from Ibbenburen to Nordenham. Stinnes required a commission and the importers and wholesalers had to pay for the cost of sea transport, including trimming and unloading costs. The wholesalers would take their cut and the price the householder paid would also include a profit element for the retailer.
(5) In January 1996 the £/DEM rate was 2.236 and rose to 2.950 by the middle of 1997 when Preussag removed itself from the British market.
(6) During the early 1990s the supply of anthracite from outside Europe was increasing: China, Vietnam and South Africa, in particular. It was only after British Coal was denationalised in 1994 that prices in the anthracite market started to fall. It was noted in March 1995 at a meeting attended by representatives of Stinnes, Preussag and BFL that the market was "extremely competitive" and that unless market prices were not followed, Preussag would lose market share.
(7) During 1995 the market was further under pressure from the intervention of three Welsh collieries and one, Tower, was claiming some success in displacing imported product from European markets [namely the German producers].
(8) Traditionally all coal products cost more in the winter season but there had been a mild winter in 1994/5 and Preussag made no shipments in November and December 1995 because their distributors were over stocked.
(9) In September 1995 Celtic set up a forward land sale in Hull and, as the witness says, this was a significant development. Stinnes considered this to be "stiff competition" and a direct challenge to Preussag's export trade to the east coast. Accordingly, at a meeting in November 1995 it was clear that Preussag would need to adjust its prices downwards by at least £10 per tonne if it was going to remain in the market. Celtic were reportedly doing well and the market for Ibbenburen anthracite was collapsing. Supply had increased by 25% and demand had continued to fall, and the 1995/6 winter was also mild. It was BFL's view that it was the intent of the Welsh producers to drive out imports and, thus, Preussag, from the market and when this was achieved raise prices after a complete market dominance had been achieved. Preussag gave BFL a target of 80,000 tonnes in the British market.
(10) Preussag agreed a substantial ["huge"] price cut of £18 per tonne as from the beginning of 1996 to below the cost of production. Preussag's marketing strategy was to undercut Celtic's prices.
"If we had refused to decrease our prices and BFL had stopped taking our product we would have had no chance of persuading another wholesaler in England to take our product at those higher prices."
The effect of this reduction was to "cause havoc" in the UK trade and Preussag had to compensate organisations which already held stocks of their anthracite which had been purchased at the higher prices.
(11) Preussag suspected that BFL were not passing the full increase on, but were increasing the amount of the commission which they kept for themselves. Following meetings with BFL, the witness says that he persuaded BFL to accept a "de facto price increase of £9.00 per tonne in April 1996". This was not a real increase; Preussag simply refused to reduce the price yet further by the usual summer price discount. By the end of 1996 the prices were higher but still lower than they had been in 1995. And the exchange rate was moving in favour of Preussag and "the effect of this was to make the low prices far more affordable". The target of 80,000 tonnes was exceeded, as the Commission indicates: Preussag sold 98,000 tonnes into the British market in 1996 which is nearly 50% of the high quality anthracite segment of the market, namely 200,000 tonnes.
(12) Preussag withdrew from the British market in the summer of 1997 because of the complaints which were beginning to be made about the presence of German producers and their prices and at the time Preussag was proposing to enter into an important merger in Germany and the continuing complaints were unhelpful both to that project and to the new settlement which Germany was seeking for the aid programme for their coal industry in 1997.
(13) Celtic's complaints to the Commission were settled commercially by agreement in March 1998 but despite this settlement, and Celtic and Preussag's joint representations, the Commission continued to pursue the complaint and made their Decision.
(1) Betws colliery was worked successfully from 1978 until the mid 1990's whilst in the ownership of British Coal. A rich seam called the Red Vein was being exploited with the use of automated long wall mining techniques. When this seam was exhausted, attempts were made to exploit the four foot seam in the same way, but as British Coal was on the verge of being privatised, there was no real incentive to undertake this work, which was considered to be more difficult. Accordingly, British Coal decided to close the mine in 1992.
(2) The Government's professional advisers having surveyed the mine concluded that although the mine was effectively exhausted in terms of long wall mining techniques there was still a residue of coal which could be successfully mined using more traditional methods and Mr Cook and a number of other enterprising ex employees pooled their redundancy money and took over the operation of the colliery and set up the Claimant company in July 1993, with substantial finance [£2 million] provided by Barclays Bank.
(3) In order to acquire the mine, British Coal had to be satisfied that there was a viable plan for the future mining. Mining could only be carried out in Britain with a licence from British Coal . Accordingly full proposals were worked up setting out details of the proposed financing, methods of working, and proper sales and marketing plans. It was anticipated that there was 20 years of life left working both the red vein seam and the four foot seam. British Coal's view was that the four foot seam was unviable and the proposals were adjusted to reflect this fact. Thus the plan was for a life of ten years based upon an annual output of 100,000 tonnes per year. A major part of the strategy was to "diversify markets". At the time of acquisition, 65% of Betws' production was untreated small coal for use in blending for power stations. Only 35% of the output was for the premium domestic market. The company proposed that a new "washery" should be introduced so that small washed coal could be produced for sale to manufacturers of smokeless fuel.
(4) Betws entered into a five year marketing agreement with an entity called Enerco, a coal trading company. Enerco in turn entered into a back to back agreement with Anglo, the main competitor of BFL. Under the arrangements, Anglo were obliged to purchase all graded coal sold by Betws to Enerco. Enerco were also involved in coal preparation and Betws bought from them, through a credit sale agreement, a new washery for just over half £1 million. The final payment under the agreement was made on June 2001.
(5) Production commenced on 26 April 1994 and by October that year production was running at the rate of 100,000 tonnes per annum. Also in October 1994 the new washery came on stream.
(6) In 1995, sales of graded anthracite became difficult and stocks began to increase. Betws' reaction was to reduce prices. Preussag had made its first price reduction in February 1995. About 40% of Betws total production was graded anthracite [39,407 tonnes from a total of 105,053 tonnes]. Anglo was finding it hard to compete with what Mr Cook describes as Preussag's aggressive pricing policy. And through the summer of that year Betws were unable to remove the summer discount and stocks were high. Anglo were acquired by CPL who became Betws' main customer. By the end of the year the company managed to break even. But their financial backers were becoming concerned and arrangements had to be made to extend their credit for the payment of royalties under the licence and VAT. He said that "the need to do so was a direct consequence of lower prices resulting from the price war." If selling prices had been higher then the overdraft and interest charges would have been lower.
"in the absence of subsidised Ibbenburen coal there would have been the opportunity to sell much more. The increase in sales of anthracite between 1995 and 1996 (32,000 tonnes) noted by the European Commission was more than 80% of our total production of graded anthracite." [see paragraph 32 of Mr Cook's witness statement].
If prices had not fallen, Mr Cook says that his mine could have increased production to 127,000 tonnes per annum.
(7) The output from Betws for the 1996/7 year was 116,026 of which 37,007 were graded, and prices fell again in 1996. The Directors noted that there was "surplus productive capacity together with cheap imports being 'dumped' [which had] led to a fall in prices as producers sought to retain volumes". Although graded anthracite represented at this time about 35% of the total production it represented about 63% of turnover.
(8) In 1997/8 out of a total production of 112,073 tonnes 38,443 was graded and this slightly higher proportion reflected the fact that stocks had reduced (having returned to normal operational levels by the summer of 1997).
(9) The Bank made a further advance to Betws to enable it to refurbish the entrance to the four foot seam to enable production to commence there. That phase was complete by September 1998 and full production commenced in May 1999. Mr Cook says that all this took longer than necessary and stemmed from their inability to generate sufficient cash due to the price war for graded anthracite.
(10) Betws lodged a formal complaint to the Commission on 12 June 1998 and the Commission subsequently confirmed that their decision also applied to them as it
"concerns in fact [Preussag's] behaviour as regards the whole market. That includes [Betws], therefore the reasoning of the Decision of 29 July 1998 in this matter addresses your concerns."
Submissions on Causation and Quantum
Have Betws shown on a balance of probabilities that the unlawful activities of Preussag were an effective cause of financial loss to them?
Betws does not have to show that the activities were the main, principal or only cause of the loss claimed. Nor is it sufficient that the Court should apply a 'but for' test of causation. Effective cause means what it says and requires no further elaboration.
(1) The only aid which the Commission say that Preussag had misused was the equivalent of £6.5 million. he points out that Betws' pleaded case is that Preussag's pricing policy was "only possible" because the company had misused the unauthorised State aid for the years 1996 and 1997. Further, for the purpose of calculating damages, Dr Rix had worked on the assumption that Preussag would have had to have withdrawn from the market at the beginning of 1996. Effectively, the Commission authorised the balance of the aid and the only unlawfulness must be linked only to the £6.5 million.
(2) As a matter of fact I should accept the evidence of Mr Kalenscher that Preussag were determined to stay in the market to protect their investment in goodwill. The stocks had been written down and a book profit was realisable. It was an incontrovertible proposition that the reductions in price could not have been sustained in the long run; but that was not what Preussag were looking for. Accordingly, there is no evidence that the existence of the £6.5 million played any part at all in Preussag's decisions and marketing strategy.
(3) It was Celtic who destabilised the market. Preussag were responding to Celtic's attack on them and Betws were simply caught in the middle of a price war. Celtic were aiming to drive from the market not just Preussag but also their wholesale agent BFL. Removal of Preussag from the market would not have stabilised prices, as BFL would have filled the gap with Chinese coal. BFL merely sought to respond to Celtic's threat. Mr Kalenscher wished to maintain Preussag's position in the market and took no commercial decision to disadvantage Betws. Preussag were under pressure from BFL to reduce their prices; that was not their choice. Had Preussag been unwilling to reduce prices BFL would have turned to Chinese coal.
(4) Preussag played no part in the decision to ship a relatively small quantity of anthracite into South Wales. That was a decision taken by BFL on a tit-for-tat basis and when Mr Kalenscher heard of it he made his views known and no further shipment was made.
(5) By the end of 1995, Betws had reduced prices for reasons wholly unconnected with the 'misuse' of £6.5 million [which related to 1996 and 1997] yet for the purposes of the claim it is asserted that the 1994 prices would have continued had Preussag left the market at the end of 1995. Betws was not following Preussag's prices. Its concern was with Celtic's prices and Betws prices followed Celtic's prices down.
(6) There were other forces affecting the market, such as the mild weather, the growth in good quality product from China and the Tower colliery's ability to produce a higher quality product than before of which about 100,000 tonnes was available.
(7) In summary, Betws did not reduce its prices to those of Preussag. Betws was always priced so as to undercut Celtic and as Celtic reduced their prices [through CGC] so Anglo reduced theirs to Anglo.
(1) The new policy adopted by Celtic was perceived to be a threat to Preussag's established market and was regarded as stiff competition. At the meeting on 15 December 1995, Preussag were concerned that their sales had collapsed or were collapsing: there had been no imports in November or December. The decision was taken to reduce prices substantially [by as much as £18 per tonne for the top grade] with immediate effect until March of that year. The suggestion that Preussag was 'forced' by BFL into this decision is not established on the evidence.
(2) The purpose of the price cut was to undercut the Welsh competitors [principally Celtic] and meant reducing prices below the cost of production.
(3) The low prices "severely disrupted the market" and necessitated the payment by Preussag of compensation to those stockholders who had bought Preussag product at the higher prices. The Commission concluded that Preussag's prices during 1996/7 were "systematically lower" than Celtic's prices and that Preussag were offering major reductions on their list prices. Their pricing policy was a matter of concern to HMG and it made a formal complaint to the Commission about Preussag at the beginning of November 1996. At the same time, Preussag were increasing their exports to the UK so that they rose to 95,000 tonnes in 1996 "all the more remarkable as it took place in difficult market conditions." [Commission Decision [paragraphs 29-32]. By their reduction in price below the cost of production, Preussag were able to take 50% of the high quality anthracite market.
(4) Dr Rix expressed the view that Betws' products competed directly with those from Preussag's mine and Betws had to reduce prices accordingly. Betws was in the premium end of the market; its product was of higher quality that Celtic's and the coal from the red Vein seam was regarded as probably the best in the world.
(5) The anthracite market in Britain is national rather than regional because the only sustainable price difference is in transport costs. A price cut by one supplier would have an impact nationally. That is confirmed by the fact that the wholesalers were not confined to a region or to the west or east coast of Britain.
(6) There is no evidence to support Herr Kalenscher's suspicion that the price cut did not reach the consumer and was absorbed by BFL for their own benefit.
(7) The tables produced by Mr Sharpe during the hearing were not reliable and in any event show that the prices seem remarkably similar which shows that Betws prices were being powered to meet Preussag's prices.
(8) Effectively, at the end of 1995, Preussag were faced with three choices: to increase prices to comply with the Commission's findings, which would not have been commercially feasible; withdraw from the market; seek additional State Aid which would only have been granted on condition that there could be no undercutting of the prices of Welsh producers. Preussag cannot be heard to say, contrary to the Commission's findings, that they could have sold coal in the UK without the use of State Aid.
(9) Chinese coal would not have filled the void if Preussag had left the market and would not have under priced the Welsh producers.
(1) Preussag used its State aid to enable it to sell anthracite into the British market as from January 1996 at prices substantially below the costs of production.
(2) The decision taken to make the huge or substantial price cut as from January 1996 was an attempt by Preussag to undercut the Welsh producers who were seeking to enter Preussag's east coast market, and to ensure additional Preussag quantities in the market. The purpose was to 'see off' [my words] the potentially burgeoning Welsh entry into the market. If Preussag wished to maintain or increase its market share it had to make this reduction or else it would have to leave the market. The existence of the State Aid and the fact that production costs for the imported coal had not been separated from the other costs of production enabled Preussag to pursue a marketing strategy which would otherwise have not been available to it. It could not compete with Welsh coal, which was cheap to mine by comparison. I reject the submission that BFL pressured Preussag to reduce prices. Herr Kalenscher is, I suspect, a tough business man. I am sure that in principle, like most businesses, Preussag did not relish the idea of reducing prices. But he had a clear decision to make: reduce prices and undercut the Welsh producers or lose the market. He was quite free to choose the latter course, but decided against and exploited Preussag's financial position to stay in the market. I also reject the thesis advanced by Mr Sharpe that Preussag was the victim, so to speak, of Celtic's disruption of the market and was only protecting itself from damage. It is true that Celtic were a threat to Preussag's exports to the UK because, having cheaper production costs they could afford to undercut the Ibbenburen product. Celtic were entitled to face competition from Preussag but only fair competition in the sense that State Aid was not available to assist production intended for the domestic market. Whether the amount of aid misused was as the Commission determined or not, it was the fact that Preussag were able to market their coal at below the cost of production which was harmful to the British market. This was unfair competition. But as I have already said, because the Commission decision was directed to the State and not Preussag as an undertaking, the Commission have not had a chance to consider the extent to which Preussag's pricing policy was predatory or improper. I am proceeding on the assumption that Preussag have acted unlawfully and that their unlawful act lies in them using subsidies intended for one market in another.
(3) The effect of this price cut was dramatic and effective. Preussag increased its exports at the expense of the Welsh producers, and existing stockholders of Preussag coal had to be compensated because they had bought at a price which was no longer viable. I accept Dr Rix's opinion that the price cut "caused havoc in the UK trade." Preussag's prices were systematically lower than those of the Welsh producers despite the real difference in production costs.
(3) The British market is relatively small and is, effectively, national although there are different regions. The only real difference in prices should reflect the difference in transport costs. Betws were affected by the price war being conducted by Preussag. The point was well made by Mr Port, the former Chief Officer of BFL. At paragraph 34 of his witness statement he said this:
"As a matter of practical reality, German Coal produced by Preussag tended to be sold in the east of the country, while coal from Wales (including that of Betws) tended to be sold in the West. Nevertheless, the same price reduction pressures applied in both sides of the country. All coal producers, including Preussag and Betws came under pressure to follow Celtic's lead by reducing their wholesale prices. It therefore follows that wholesale prices had to fall across the board, and the producers had little choice but to comply with our requests of they wanted to continue in the UK market."
(4) Herr Kalenscher's suspicion that BFL were not passing on the price reduction but were feathering their own nest, is unsupported on the evidence. It is contradicted by Dr Rix who said that it was misleading to suggest that BFL did not reduce the price in the market, and was not supported by Mr Port either. The price reduction was notorious within the market and everyone in the market knew about it when it was made. The room for BFL not to pass on the reduction was minimal.
(5) It can be seen from Dr Rix's reports that the price reductions made by Betws follow the market prices down, as would be inevitable if it wished to remain in business.
(6) The price tables produced by Preussag during the course of the hearing are not reliable. List prices are not a reliable indicator of actual prices because there may be discounts and the prices themselves may include or exclude transport costs. In other words one would need to know whether the prices were ex ship or ex store or on a delivered basis. The attempt to increase Preussag's prices by adding to them a notional cost of transport calculated at £4 per tonne per 100 miles is unconvincing. BFL were not asked about this during the evidence of Mr Port. These figures were produced during the cross-examination of Dr Rix in an attempt to show that the Preussag price increase did not have any or any significant impact on the market. Frankly, from an evidential point of view, I regard the tables as interesting but not valuable.
(7) Had Preussag been required to charge a price which truly covered the unsubsidised cost of production, then they would have had to leave the market as from the beginning of 1996.
(8) I am not convinced by the theory that Celtic would have gone on reducing prices simply to drive BFL out of business. The notion that the Chinese could immediately fill the gap left by Preussag involves an assumption that there would have been investment available; that the Chinese were satisfied that the market was there in a continuing stream and was a viable proposition. Fear of a continuing price war would have been a deterrent to the Chinese trade. I cannot discount the possibility that some Chinese imports would have filled the gap and I am not prepared to assume that Betws would have been able to increase their prices to the extent they claim [see under quantum].
(9) It seems to me on a balance of probabilities that Preussag's continued presence in the market selling a product below the cost of production and misusing State aid to do so has caused some loss and damage to their competitors. If there is a Community Law tort as suggested and postulated in this part of the case, it would seem to me that the only pre-requisite, as a matter of domestic law, is that the Claimant is a 'neighbour,' in the legal sense, of the wrongdoer. I assume that an intent to injure is not required for this tort, but that a person who was reasonably foreseeably likely to be affected by the wrongful actions of the wrongdoer would satisfy the neighbour test. Betws were a Welsh producer who were known to Preussag's distribution agents. Their product was known to Herr Kalenscher. Whilst I accept that the decision taken by Preussag was not 'aimed at' Betws, that is not a legal requirement, I assume, of the Community tort upon which Mr Brealey relies. If the hypothetical reasonable person in Herr Kalenscher's shoes had asked whether the consequence of the dramatic price reduction would be likely to harm Betws, the answer would be yes.
Damages
(1) The revenue which Betws lost as a result of Preussag's price cutting
(2) The increased overdraft payments stemming from the loss of revenue
(3) The loss of profit which Betws would have made on increased production
(4) The costs flowing from the delay in development work on the four-foot seam.
Head 1
Head 2
Head 3
Head 4
Conclusion