BAILII is celebrating 24 years of free online access to the law! Would you consider making a contribution?
No donation is too small. If every visitor before 31 December gives just £1, it will have a significant impact on BAILII's ability to continue providing free access to the law.
Thank you very much for your support!
[Home] [Databases] [World Law] [Multidatabase Search] [Help] [Feedback] | ||
United Kingdom House of Lords Decisions |
||
You are here: BAILII >> Databases >> United Kingdom House of Lords Decisions >> C Czarnikow Ltd v Koufos (The Heron II) [1967] UKHL 4 (17 October 1967) URL: http://www.bailii.org/uk/cases/UKHL/1967/4.html Cite as: [1969] AC 350, [1967] UKHL 4, [1969] 1 AC 350 |
[New search] [Buy ICLR report: [1969] 1 AC 350] [Help]
Parliamentary
Archives,
HL/PO/JU/4/3/1155
HOUSE OF LORDS
v.
C. CZARNIKOW LIMITED
Lord Reid
Lord
Morris
of Borth-y-
Gest
Lord
Hodson
Lord Pearce
Lord
Upjohn
Lord Reid
my lords
By charter
Party of 15th October, 1960 the Respondents chartered the
Appellant's
Vessel, Heron II, to proceed to Constanza, there to load a cargo
of
3,000 tons of sugar; and to carry it to Basrah, or, in the
Charterer's option,
to Jeddah. The vessel left Constanza on 1st
November. The option was
not exercised and the vessel arrived at
Basrah on 2nd December The Umpire
has found that " a
reasonably accurate prediction of the length of the voyage
"
was twenty days ". But the vessel had in breach of contract made
deviations
which caused a delay of nine days.
It was the
intention of the Respondents to sell the sugar " promptly
after
" arrival at Basrah and after inspection by merchants
". The Appellant did
not know this but he was aware of the
fact that there was a market for sugar
at Basrah. The sugar was in
fact sold at Basrah in lots between 12th and 22nd
December but
shortly before that time the market price had fallen partly by
reason
of the arrival of another cargo of sugar. It was found by the
Umpire
that if there had not been this delay of nine days the
sugar would have fetched
£32 10s. Od. per ton. The actual
price realised was only £31 2s. 9d. per ton.
The Respondents
claim that they are entitled to recover the difference as
damage
for breach of contract. The Appellant admits that he is liable to
pay
interest for nine days on the value of the sugar and certain
minor expenses but
denies that fall in market value can be taken
into account in assessing damages
in this case.
McNair J.,
following the decision in The Parana L.R. 2 PD 118,
decided
this question in favour of the Appellant. He said:
" In
those circumstances it seems to me almost impossible to say that
"
the shipowner must have known that the delay in prosecuting the
"
voyage would probably result, or be likely to result, in this kind of
loss."
The Court
of Appeal by a majority (Diplock and Salmon L.JJ., Sellers
L.J.
dissenting) reversed the decision of the trial judge. The
majority held that
The Parana laid down no general rule,
and, applying the rule (or rules) in
Hadley and Another v.
Baxendale and Others (1854) 9 Ex 341 as explained in
Victoria
Laundry (Windsor) Ltd. v. Newman Industries Ltd. [1949] 2
K.B 528,
they held that the loss due to fall in market price was
not too remote to be
recoverable as damages.
It may be
well first to set out the knowledge and intention of the
parties
at the time of making the contract so far as relevant or argued to
be
relevant. The Charterers intended to sell the sugar in the
market at Basrah
on arrival of the vessel. They could have changed
their mind and exercised
their option to have the sugar delivered
at Jeddah but they did not do so.
There is no finding that they
had in mind any particular date as the likely date
of arrival at
Basrah or that they had any knowledge or expectation that in
late
November or December there would be a rising or a falling
market. The
shipowner was given no information about these matters
by the Charterers.
He did not know what the Charterers intended to
do with the sugar. But
he knew there was a market in sugar at
Basrah, and it appears to me that,
if he had thought about the
matter, he must have realised that at least it
was not unlikely
that the sugar would be sold in the market at market
price on
arrival. And he must be held to have known that in any
ordinary
market prices are apt to fluctuate from day to day: but
he had no reason
to suppose it more probable that during the
relevant period such fluctuation
2
would be
downwards rather than upwards—it was an even chance that
the
fluctuation would be downwards.
So the
question for decision is whether a plaintiff can recover as
damages
for breach of contract a loss of a kind which the
defendant, when he made
the contract, ought to have realised was
not unlikely to result from a breach
of contract causing delay in
delivery. I use the words " not unlikely " as
denoting a
degree of probability considerably less than an even chance
but
nevertheless not very unusual and easily foreseeable.
For over a
century everyone has agreed that remoteness of damage in
contract
must be determined by applying the rule (or rules) laid down by
a
Court including Lord Wensleydale (then Parke B.), Martin B and
Alderson B.
in Hadley v. Baxendale. But many
different interpretations of that rule
have been adopted by judges
at different times. So I think that one ought
first to see just
what was decided in that case, because it would seem wrong
to
attribute to that rule a meaning which, if it had been adopted in
that
case, would have resulted in a contrary decision of that
case.
In Hadley
v. Baxendale the owners of a flour mill at Gloucester
which
was driven by a steam engine delivered to common carriers,
Pickford & Co.,
a broken crank shaft to be sent to engineers
in Greenwich. A delay of
five days in delivery there was held to
be in breach of contract and the
question at issue was the proper
measure of damages. In fact the shaft
was sent as a pattern for a
new shaft and until it arrived the mill could
not operate. So the
owners claimed £300 as loss of profit for the five
days by
which resumption of work was delayed by this breach of contract.
But
the carriers did not know that delay would cause loss of this kind.
Alderson B. delivering the judgment of the Court said (at page 355) :
" We
find that the only circumstances here communicated by the
"
plaintiffs to the defendants at the time the contract was made were
"
that the article to be carried was the broken shaft of a mill, and
that
" the plaintiffs were the millers of that mill. But how
do these circum-
" stances show reasonably that the profits
of the mill must be stopped
" by an unreasonable delay in the
delivery of the broken shaft by the
" carrier to the third
person? Suppose the plaintiffs had another shaft
" in their
possession put up or putting up at the time, and that they
"
only wished to send back the broken shaft to the engineer who made
"
it; it is clear that this would be quite consistent with the above
"
circumstances, and yet the unreasonable delay in the delivery would
"
have no effect upon the intermediate profits of the mill. Or,
again,
" suppose that at the time of the delivery to the
carrier the machinery
" of the mill had been in other
respects defective, then also the same
" results would
follow."
Then,
having said that in fact the loss of profit was caused by the
delay,
he continued:
" But
it is obvious that in the great multitude of cases of millers
"
sending off broken shafts to third persons by a carrier' under
ordinary
" circumstances, such consequences would not, in all
probability, have
" occurred."
Alderson
B. clearly did not and could not mean that it was not
reasonably
foreseeable that delay might stop the resumption of
work in the mill. He
merely said that in the great multitude—which
I take to mean the great
majority—of cases this would not
happen. He was not distinguishing
between results which were
foreseeable or unforeseeable, but between
results which were
likely because they would happen in the great majority
of cases,
and results which were unlikely because they would only happen
in
a small minority of cases. He continued:
" It
follows, therefore, that the loss of profits here cannot reasonably
"
be considered such a consequence of the breach of contract as could
"
have been fairly and reasonably contemplated by both the parties
"
when they made this contract."
He clearly
meant that a result which will happen in the great majority of
cases
should fairly and reasonably be regarded as having been in the
3
contemplation
of the parties, but that a result which, though foreseeable
as a
substantial possibility, would only happen in a small minority of
cases
should not be regarded as having been in their
contemplation. He was
referring to such a result when he
continued:
" For
such loss would neither have flowed naturally from the breach
"
of this contract in the great multitude of such cases occurring
under
" ordinary circumstances, nor were the special
circumstances, which
" perhaps would have made it a
reasonable and natural consequence
" of such breach of
contract, communicated to or known by the
" defendants."
I have
dealt with the latter part of the judgment before coming to the
well
known rule because the Court were there applying the rule and
the
language which was used in the latter part appears to me to
throw consider-
able light on the meaning which they must have
attached to the rather vague
expressions used in the rule itself.
The rule is that the damages " should
" be such as may
fairly and reasonably be considered either arising naturally,
"
i.e. according to the usual course of things from such breach of
contract
" itself, or such as may reasonably be supposed to
have been in the con-
" templation of both parties at the
time they made the contract as the
" probable result of the
breach of it".
I do not
think that it was intended that there were to be two rules
or that
two different standards or tests were to be applied. The last
two
passages which I quoted from the end of the judgment applied
to the facts
before the Court which did not include any special
circumstances communica-
ted to the defendants ; and the line of
reasoning there is that because in
the great majority of cases
loss of profit would not in all probability have
occurred, it
followed that this could not reasonably be considered as having
been
fairly and reasonably contemplated by both the parties, for it
would
not have flowed naturally from the breach in the great
majority of cases.
I am
satisfied that the Court did not intend that every type of
damage
which was reasonably foreseeable by the parties when the
contract was made
should either be considered as arising naturally
i.e. in the usual course of
things or be supposed to have been in
the contemplation of the parties.
Indeed the decision makes it
clear that a type of damage which was plainly
foreseeable as a
real possibility but which would only occur in a small minority
of
cases cannot be regarded as arising in the usual course of things or
be
supposed to have been in the contemplation of the parties: the
parties are
not supposed to contemplate as grounds for the
recovery of damage any
type of loss or damage which on the
knowledge available to the defendant
would appear to him as only
likely to occur in a small minority of cases.
In cases
like Hadley v. Baxendale or the present case it is not
enough that
in fact the plaintiff's loss was directly caused by
the defendant's breach of
contract. It clearly was so caused in
both. The crucial question is whether,
on the information
available to the defendant when the contract was made,
he should,
or the reasonable man in his position would, have realised that
such
loss was sufficiently likely to result from the breach of contract to
make
it proper to hold that the loss flowed naturally from the
breach or that loss
of that kind should have been within his
contemplation.
The modern
rule in tort is quite different and it imposes a much
wider
liability. The defendant will be liable for any type of
damage which is
reasonably foreseeable as liable to happen even in
the most unusual case,
unless the risk is so small that a
reasonable man would in the whole circum-
stances feel justified
in neglecting it. And there is good reason for the
difference. In
contract, if one party wishes to protect himself against a
risk
which to the other party would appear unusual, he can direct the
other
party's attention to it before the contract is made, and I
need not stop to
consider in what circumstances the other party
will then be held to have
accepted responsibility in that event.
But in tort there is no opportunity
for the injured party to
protect himself in that way, and the tortfeasor cannot
reasonably
complain if he has to pay for some very unusual but nevertheless
4
foreseeable
damage which results from his wrongdoing. I have no doubt
that
to-day a tortfeasor would be held liable for a type of damage as
unlikely
as was the stoppage of Hadley's Mill for lack of a
crankshaft: to anyone
with the knowledge the carrier had that may
have seemed unlikely but the
chance of it happening would have
been seen to be far from negligible. But
it does not at all follow
that Hadley v. Baxendale would to-day be differently
decided.
As long
ago as 1872 Willes J. said in Home v. Midland Railway Co.
L.R.
7 C.P. 583 at page 590:
" The
cases as to the measure of damages for a tort do not apply
"
to a case of contract. That was suggested in a case in Bulstrode
but
" the notion was corrected in Hadley v. Baxendale.
The damages are
" to be limited to those that are the
natural and ordinary consequences
" which may be supposed to
have been in the contemplation of the
" parties at the time
of making the contract."
And in Cory v. Thames Ironworks L.R. 3 Q.B. 181 Blackburn J said (at
page 190):
" I
think it all comes to this: the measure of damages when a party
"
has not fulfilled his contract is what might be reasonably expected
"
in the ordinary course of things to flow from the non-fulfilment of
the
" contract, not more than that, but what might be
reasonably expected
" to flow from the non-fulfilment of the
contract in the ordinary state of
" things, and to be the
natural consequences of it. The reason why the
" damages are
confined to that is, I think, pretty obvious, viz. that
" if
the damage were exceptional and unnatural damage, to be made
"
liable for that would be hard upon the seller because if he had
known
" what the consequences would be he would probably have
stipulated for
" more time or, at all events, have used
greater exertions if he knew
" that that extreme mischief
would follow from the non-fulfilment of
" his contract."
It is true
that in some later cases opinions were expressed that the measure
of
damages is the same in tort as it is in contract, but those were
generally
cases where it was sought to limit damages due for a
tort and not cases where
it was sought to extend damages due for
breach of contract, and I do
not recollect any case in which such
opinions were based on a full con-
sideration of the matter. In my
view these opinions must now be regarded
as erroneous.
For a
considerable time there was a tendency to set narrow limits to
awards
of damages. Such phrases were used as that the damage was
not "
the immediate and necessary effect of the breach of contract"
(per
Cockburn C.J. in Hobbs v. The London and South
Western Railway Com-
pany L.R. 10 Q.B. 111 at page 118). The
Parana was decided during that
period. But later a more
liberal tendency can be seen. I do not think it
useful to review
the authorities in detail but I do attach importance to what
was
said in this House in R. & H. Hall, Ltd. v. W. H. Pim
(Junior)
& Co. Ltd. (1928) 33 Com. Cas. 324.
In that
case Pim sold a cargo of wheat to Hall but failed to deliver it.
Hall
had resold the wheat but as a result of Pim's breach of contract
lost
the profit which they would have made on their sub-sale.
Three of their
Lordships dealt with the case on the basis that the
relevant question was
whether it ought to have been in the
contemplation of the parties that a
resale was probable. The
finding of the arbitrators was:
" The
arbitrators are unable to find that it was in the contemplation
"
of the parties or ought to have been in the contemplation of
Messrs.
" Pim at that time that the cargo would be resold or
was likely to be
" resold before delivery: in fact, the
chances of its being resold as a
" cargo and of its being
taken delivery of by Messrs. Hall were about
" equal."
On that
finding the Court of Appeal had decided in favour of Pim,
saying
that, as the arbitrators had stated as a fact that the
chances of the cargo
5
being
resold or not being resold were equal, it was therefore "idle
to
" speak of a likelihood or of a probability of a resale ".
Lord
Dunedin pointed out that it was for the Court to decide what was
to
be supposed to have been in the contemplation of the parties, and
then
said:
" I
do not think that ' probability' . . . means that the chances
"
are all in favour of the event happening. To make a thing probable
"
it is enough, in my view, that there is an even chance of its
happening.
" That is the criterion I apply; and in view of
the facts, as I have said
" above, I think there was here in
the contemplation of parties the
" probability of a resale."
He did not
have to consider how much less than a fifty per cent chance
would
amount to a probability in this sense.
Lord Shaw went rather farther. He said:
" To
what extent in a contract of goods for future delivery the
"
extent of damages is in contemplation of parties is always
extremely
" doubtful. The main business fact is that they are
thinking of the
" contract being performed and not of its
being not performed. But
" with regard to the latter if their
contract shows that there were
" instances or stages which
made ensuing losses or damage a not un-
" likely result of
the breach of the contract, then all such results must
" be
reckoned to be within not only the scope of the contract, but the
"
contemplation of parties as to its breach."
Lord
Phillimore was less definite and perhaps went even farther. He
said
that the sellers of the wheat knew that the buyers " might well
sell it
" over again and make a profit on the resale " ;
and that being so they " must
" be taken to have
consented to this state of things and thereby to have
" made
themselves liable to pay " the profit on a resale.
It may be
that there was nothing very new in this but I think that Hall's
case
must be taken to have established that damages are not to be
regarded
as too remote merely because, on the knowledge available
to the defendant
when the contract was made, the chance of the
occurrence of the event which
caused the damage would have
appeared to him to be rather less than an
even chance. I would
agree with Lord Shaw that it is generally sufficient
that that
event would have appeared to the defendant as not unlikely to
occur.
It is hardly ever possible in this matter to assess
probabilities with any
degree of mathematical accuracy. But I do
not find in that case or in cases
which preceded it any warrant
for regarding as within the contemplation
of the parties any event
which would not have appeared to the defendant,
had he thought
about it, to have a very substantial degree of probability.
But then
it has been said that the liability of defendants has been
further
extended by Victoria Laundry (Windsor) Ltd. v.
Newman Industries Ltd.
[1949] 2 K.B. 528. I do not think
so. The plaintiffs bought a large boiler
from the defendants and
the defendants were aware of the general nature of
the plaintiffs'
business and of the plaintiffs' intention to put the boiler into
use
as soon as possible. Delivery of the boiler was delayed in breach
of
contract and the plaintiffs claimed as damages loss of profit
caused by the
delay. A large part of the profits claimed would
have resulted from some
specially lucrative contracts which the
plaintiffs could have completed if
they had had the boiler: that
was rightly disallowed because the defendants
had no knowledge of
these contracts. But Asquith L. J. then said:
" It
does not however follow that the plaintiffs are precluded from
"
recovering some general (and perhaps conjectural) sum for loss of
"
business in respect of dyeing contracts to be reasonably expected,
any
" more than in respect of laundering contracts to be
reasonably
" expected."
It appears
to me that this was well justified on the earlier authorities. It
was
certainly not unlikely on the information which the defendants
had
when making the contract that delay in delivering the boiler
would result
in loss of business: indeed it would seem that that
was more than an even
6
chance.
And there was nothing new in holding that damages should be
estimated
on a conjectural basis. This House had approved of that as early
as
1813 in Hall v. Ross 1 Dow. 201.
But what
is said to create a " landmark " is the statement of
principles
by Asquith L. J. on pages 539-40. This does to some
extent go beyond the
older authorities and in so far as it does
so, I do not agree with it. In
paragraph (2) it is said that the
plaintiff is entitled to recover " such part
" of the
loss actually resulting as was at the time of the contract
reasonably
" foreseeable as liable to result from the breach
". To bring in reasonable
foreseeability appears to me to be
confusing measure of damages in contract
with measure of damages
in tort. A great many extremely unlikely results
are reasonably
foreseeable: it is true that Lord Asquith may have meant
foreseeable
as a likely result, and if that is all he meant I would not
object
farther than to say that I think that the phrase is liable
to be misunder-
stood. For the same reason I would take exception
to the phrase " liable
" to result" in paragraph
(5). Liable is a very vague word but I think that
one would
usually say that when a person foresees a very improbable result
he
foresees that it is liable to happen.
I agree
with the first half of paragraph (6). For the best part of a
century
it has not been required that the defendant could have
foreseen that a breach
of contract must necessarily result in the
loss which has occurred. But I cannot
agree with the second half
of that paragraph. It has never been held to be
sufficient in
contract that the loss was foreseeable as " a serious
possibility "
or " a real danger " or as being "
on the cards ". It is on the cards that one can
win £100,000
or more for a stake of a few pence—several people have
done
that. And anyone who backs a hundred to one chance regards a
win as a
serious possibility—many people have won on such a
chance. And the
Wagon Mound No. 2 [1966] 3 WLR 498 could
not have been decided as it
was unless the extremely unlikely fire
should have been foreseen by the ship's
officer as a real danger.
It appears to me that in the ordinary use of
language there is
wide gulf between saying that some event is not unlikely or
quite
likely to happen and saying merely that it is a serious possibility,
a real
danger, or on the cards. Suppose one takes a well shuffled
pack of cards, it
is quite likely or not unlikely that the top
card will prove to be a diamond : the
odds are only 3 to 1
against. But most people would not say that it is quite
likely to
be the nine of diamonds for the odds are then 51 to 1 against. On
the
other hand I think that most people would say that there is a
serious
possibility or a real danger of its being turned up first
and of course it is on the
cards. If the tests of " real
danger " or " serious possibility " are in future
to
be authoritative then the Victoria Laundry case would
indeed be a landmark
because it would mean that Hadley v.
Baxendale would be differently decided
to-day. I certainly
could not understand any Court deciding that, on the
information
available to the carrier in that case, the stoppage of the mill
was
neither a serious possibility nor a real danger. If those
tests are to prevail in
future then let us cease to pay lip
service to the rule in Hadley v. Baxendale.
But in
my judgment to adopt these tests would extend liability for breach
of
contract beyond what is reasonable or desirable. From the
limited knowledge
which I have of commercial affairs I would not
expect such an extension to be
welcomed by the business community
and from the legal point of view I can
find little or nothing to
recommend it.
Lord
Asquith took the phrases " real danger " and " serious
possibility "
from the speech of Lord du Parcq in Monarch
Steamship Co., Ltd. v.
Karlshamns Oljefabriken (A/B) [1949] AC 196 so I must examine that case.
The facts were complicated
but it is sufficient to say that a voyage was
prolonged by breach
of contract so that war broke out before it was completed,
and by
reason of an embargo imposed on the outbreak of war the cargo
owner
had to incur great expense in transshipping his goods and
having them carried
to the contract destination The contract was
made in April 1939. The
question was whether he was entitled to
recover this expense as damages for
the breach of contract and
that depended on whether the outbreak of war and
7
consequent
embargo were or ought to have been within the contemplation of
the
contracting parties in April, 1939. By that time war was much more
than
merely a serious possibility. Lord Porter said (at page 219):
" Accepting the
" view that the appellants ought to have
foreseen the likelihood of war
" occurring ...". Lord
Wright said (at page 222) " There was indeed in 1939
"
the general fear that there might be a war . . . . The possibility
must have been
" in the minds of both parties ". Lord
Uthwatt said (at page 232) that a
reasonable shipowner "
would regard the chance of war, not as a possibility
" of
academic interest to the venture, but as furnishing matter which
commer-
" daily ought to be taken into account". And
Lord Morton said (at page 235)
that the shipowner " would
feel that there was a grave risk of war breaking out
" in
Europe ". On those assessments of the situation holding that the
damage
which flowed from the outbreak of war was not too remote to
be recoverable
was well within the existing law.
I do not
think that Lord du Parcq intended to say that his view was
materially
different. Indeed he quoted from Sir Winston Churchill " No
one
" who understood the situation could doubt that it meant
in all human proba-
" bility a major war in which we should
be involved ". So there was no need
for him to go farther
than the existing law and I do not think that he intended
to do
so. It is only by taking these two phrases out of their context that
any
such intention could be inferred
It appears
to me that, without relying in any way on the Victoria
Laundry
case, and taking the principle that had already been
established, the loss of
profit claimed in this case was not too
remote to be recoverable as damages.
So it remains to consider
whether the decision in The Parana established a rule
which,
though now anomalous, should nevertheless still be followed. In
that
case owing to the defective state of the ship's engines a
voyage which ought to
have taken 65 to 70 days took 127 days, and
as a result a cargo of hemp fetched
a much smaller price than it
would have done if there had been no breach of
contract. But the
Court of Appeal held that the plaintiffs could not recover
this
loss as damages. The vital part of their judgment is on page 123:
" In
order that damages may be recovered, we must come to two
"
conclusions—first, that it was reasonably certain that the
goods would
" not be sold until they did arrive; and
secondly, that it was reasonably
" certain that they would be
sold immediately after they arrived, and that
" that was
known to the carrier at the time when the bills of lading were
"
signed."
If that
was the right test then the decision was right, and I think that
that
test was in line with a number of cases decided before or
about that time (1877).
But, as I have already said, so strict a
test has long been obsolete. And, if one
substitutes for "
reasonably certain " the words " not unlikely" or
some
similar words denoting a much smaller degree of probability,
then the whole
argument in the judgment collapses. I need not
consider whether there were
other facts which might be held to
justify the decision, but I must say that
I do not see why the
mere duration of the voyage should make much difference.
If The
Parana had always been regarded as laying down a rule so
that
carriage by sea was to be treated as different from carriage
by land, one
would have to consider whether it would be proper to
alter a rule which
had stood for nearly a century. But in Dunn
v. Bucknall Brothers [1902]
2 K.B. 614 it was held that
there was no general rule that damages could
not be recovered by
loss of market on a voyage by sea, and for special
reasons such
damages have been awarded in a number of later cases. So,
whether
The Parana is formally overruled or not. it cannot be relied
on as
establishing a rule so as to require the present case to be
decided in a way
inconsistent with the general law as it exists
to-day.
Some
importance was attached in argument to Slater v. Hoyle &
Smith,
Ltd. [1920] 2 K.B. 11 and the earlier cases there
cited. Those cases deal
with sale of goods, and I do not think it
necessary or desirable in the present
case to consider what the
rule there is, whether it conflicts with the general
principles
now established as to measure of damages, or whether, if it does
329304 A4
8
it ought
or ought not to stand. Those are much too important questions
to
be decided obiter in the present case, and I refrain from
expressing any
opinion about them.
For the reasons which I have given I would dismiss this appeal.
Lord Morris of Borth-y-Gest
MY LORDS,
The
Appellant (a shipowner) made a contract with the Respondents
(as
Charterers) for the carriage of goods by sea. As a result of
an admitted
breach of contract on the part of the shipowner the
goods were delivered at
the port of destination several days later
than they should have been delivered.
The Respondents as a result
undoubtedly suffered financial loss. They had
intended to sell the
goods as soon as the ship arrived at its destination.
They did
sell the goods after the ship arrived but in the period of the
delay
in arrival there was a fall in the market price. In
consequence they suffered
loss in that they received less than
they would have received if the Appellant
had not been in breach.
They claimed to recover their loss as damages for
breach of
contract.
The
classic judgment in Hadley v. Baxendale (1854) 9 Ex 341 has con-
tinuously been recognised as enshrining and
formulating the guiding rules
which are to be followed in deciding
whether damage which has been the
result of a breach of contract
should be paid for by the contract breaker.
The numerous reported
decisions in the years since Hadley v. Baxendale was
decided
show that sometimes there have been problems relating to the
meaning
and intention of the words used in the judgment in that case and
that
sometimes the problems have been those of ascertaining facts and
then
of relating accepted principle to the facts as found. When
consideration
has been given to the meaning and intention of the
words used in the
judgment in Hadley v. Baxendale it
has so often been manifest that words
which are but servants to
convey and express meanings—cannot always be
servants of
precision and may sometimes be given a dominance which is
above
their status. If " Language is the dress of thought", it is
the thought
that must be understood.
In the
present case the problem is that of relating principle to
ascertained
facts. The facts are carefully set out in the stated
special case the clarity of
which earned the commendation of the
learned judge. It is not necessary
to summarise them here. It will
suffice to state that the Umpire found that
the Respondents were
the shippers and were the owners of the cargo of
Hungarian sugar
at shipment and at and after discharge. Had there been
no breach
of contract the vessel would have arrived at Basrah some nine
days
or so earlier than she did arrive. The time that would be taken in
the
voyage from Constanza to Basrah could with reasonable accuracy
be pre-
dicted to be twenty days. At the date of the charter party
and at all times
thereafter it was the intention of the
Respondents to sell the sugar cash
against delivery order promptly
after arrival at Basrah and after inspection
by merchants. They
did in fact do so. Immediately after discharge the
Respondents
proceeded to permit inspection and to negotiate sales. Had
there
been no deviation and consequently no breach of contract the
selling
price of the sugar would have been one of £32 10s.
0d. per ton. The
average price realised after the late arrival of
the sugar was £31 2s. 9d. per
ton. The fall in the market
price was caused inter alia by the arrival on
schedule
(between the date, i.e. the 22nd November, when the Appellant's
ship
should have arrived had it not deviated and the date, i.e. the
2nd
December, when it did arrive) of a ship carrying 8.000 tons of
Formosan
sugar. The London price fell during November and the
first half of
December. The Basrah prices do not conform to a set
pattern but they
tend to decline during October and November to a
low point in about
December. There was however no evidence that
the decline in the London
and Basrah prices in November and the
first half of December was caused by
9
any
unusual or unpredictable factor. To these facts it may be added
that
there was at all material times a market for sugar in Basrah.
Sugar
was regularly bought and sold there in large quantities at
prices which were
published. Some 200,000 tons were sold on the
Basrah market in a year.
Prices would fluctuate considerably. The
arrival of a steamer with a cargo
of sugar would affect the
prices. The existence of the Basrah sugar market
was known to the
Appellant at and before and after the date of the charter
party
but the Appellant did not have detailed knowledge of the markets
in
Basrah nor of those in London: the London daily price
influences the Basrah
price though the latter is not directly
related to the London price. The
carriage of sugar from the Black
Sea to Iraqi ports including Basrah is a
recognised trade but a
shipowner would ordinarily have no knowledge
whether a particular
cargo has been or is to be sold prior to its arrival in
Iraq, or
whether the sugar is being shipped in order that it should be sold
in
the market on arrival. The Appellant had no actual knowledge (nor
had
his brokers) that the Respondents intended to sell the sugar
promptly after its
arrival at Basrah.
The famous
rule in Hadley v. Baxendale postulates a contract which
one
party has broken and relates to the " damages which the
other party ought to
" receive ". They are " such
as may fairly and reasonably be considered
" either arising
naturally, i.e., according to the usual course of things, from
"
such breach of contract itself, or such as may reasonably be
supposed
" to have been in the contemplation of both parties,
at the time they made
" the contract, as the probable result
of the breach of it". The judgment
proceeds to give
illustrative guidance. Thus a contract may be one actually
made
under special circumstances. If they were " communicated by
the
" plaintiffs to the defendants, and thus known to both
parties, the damages
" resulting from the breach of such a
contract, which they would reasonably
" contemplate, would be
the amount of injury which would ordinarily follow
" from a
breach of contract under these special circumstances so known and
"
communicated ". If however such special circumstances were
wholly
unknown to the contract breaker then he " at the most
could only be
" supposed to have had in his contemplation the
amount of injury which
" would arise generally, and in the
great multitude of cases not affected by
" any special
circumstances from such a breach of contract ". The
judgment
proceeds to point out that if special circumstances have
been known, then
the parties could have been provided by special
terms as to the damages to be
payable in the event of a breach: it
would be unjust to deprive them of the
advantage of so providing.
In the
present case there was no special communication of special
cir-
cumstances by reference to which the contract of carriage was
made. The
problem presented was therefore whether with the
knowledge possessed by
the parties at the time when the contract
was made the loss in fact suffered
by the Respondents due to the
delayed arrival (in breach of contract) of
the sugar could fairly
and reasonably be considered as arising naturally (i.e.
according
to the usual course of things) from such breach. When parties
enter
into a contract they do not ordinarily at such time seek to work
out
or to calculate the exact consequences of a breach of their
contract. On the
facts of the present case it is however pertinent
to pose the enquiry as to
what the natural ordinary and sensible
answer of the Appellant would have
been if he had asked himself
what the result for the Respondents would be
if he (the
Appellant) in breach of contract and therefore unjustifiably
caused
his ship to arrive at Basrah some nine or ten days later
than it could and
should have arrived. While the Appellant did not
know precisely what plans
the Respondents had made he could be
reasonably sure of one thing, namely
that they had contracted for
the Appellant's ship to proceed at all convenient
speed to its
destination because they wanted to have their cargo delivered
at
its destination at such time as the ship could be expected to arrive.
The
Appellant knew when the charter party was made (on the 15th
October,
1960) that if the vessel arrived for loading at Constanza
(it had been con-
fidently expected that she would arrive, as she
in fact did, on the 27th
October) and if the Respondents did not
(not later than five days prior to
10
the
commencement of loading) declare that they exercised the option
of
discharging the cargo at Jeddah then there was the obligation
after loading
the cargo to proceed with all convenient speed to
Basrah. The Appellant
could and should at the very least have
contemplated that if his ship was
nine days later in arriving than
it could and should have arrived some
financial loss to the
Respondents or to an endorsee of the bill of lading
might result.
I use the words " at the very least" and the word "
might"
at this stage so as to point to the problem which is
highlighted in this case.
It is here that words and phrases begin
to crowd in and to compete. Must
the loss of the Respondents be
such that the Appellant could see that it was
certain to result?
Or would it suffice if the loss was probable or was likely
to
result or was liable to result? In the present context what do these
words
denote? If there must be selection as between them which one
is to be
employed to convey the intended meaning?
I think
that it is clear that the loss need not be such that the
contract
breaker could see that it was certain to result. The
question that arises
concerns the measure of prevision which
should fairly and reasonably be
ascribed to him.
My Lords,
in applying the guidance given in Hadley v. Baxendale I
would
hope that no undue emphasis would be placed upon any one
word or phrase.
If a party has suffered some special and peculiar
loss in reference to some
particular arrangements of his which
were unknown to the other party and
were not communicated to the
other party and were not therefore in the
contemplation of the
parties at the time when they made their contract, then
it would
be unfair and unreasonable to charge the contract-breaker with
such
special and peculiar loss. If, however, there are no " special
and extra-
" ordinary circumstances beyond the reasonable
prevision of the parties "
(see the speech of Lord Wright in
Monarch Steamship Co., Ltd. v. Karlshamns
Oljefabriker
(AB) [1949] AC 196, 221) then it becomes very largely
a
question of fact as to whether in any particular case a loss can
" fairly and
" reasonably" be considered as arising
in the normal course of things.
Though in these days commercial
cases are not tried with juries, in his speech
in the Monarch
Steamship case (supra) Lord du Parcq pointed out that in
the
end what has to be decided is a question of fact and therefore a
question
proper for a jury and he added: —
"
Circumstances are so infinitely various that, however carefully
general
" rules are framed, they must be construed with some
liberality and not
" too rigidly applied. It was necessary to
lay down principles lest juries
" should be persuaded to do
injustice by imposing an undue, or perhaps
" an inadequate,
liability on a defendant. The Court must be careful,
"
however, to see that the principles laid down are never so narrowly
"
interpreted as to prevent a jury, or judge of fact, from doing
justice
" between the parties. So to use them would be to
misuse them."
If this
approach is followed then I doubt whether the necessity arises
to
express a preference or any definite preference as between
words and phrases
that were submitted for your Lordships'
consideration. The result in any
particular case need not depend
upon giving pride of place to any one of
such phrases as "
liable to result" or " likely to result" or " not
unlikely to
" result". Each one of these phrases may be
of help but so may many others.
In Smeed
v. Foord in 1859, 1 El. & El. 602, Compton, J.
referred in his
judgment (at page 616) to the doctrine of Hadley
v. Baxendale, and said:
" The
second branch of the rule there laid down appears to me to come
"
to much the same thing as the first: for damages which may
reasonably
" be supposed to have been contemplated by the
contracting parties, are
" damages which naturally arise from
a breach of the contract. I doubt
" whether, in these cases,
it is the duty of a Judge to lay down more to
" the jury than
that the plaintiff is entitled to such damages as are the
"
natural consequences of the breach of contract. The question what
"
are such natural consequences is, I think, in each case, rather for
the
11
"
jury than for the Judge; just as it is for them, not for him, to
assess
" the amount of damages."
Somewhat
comparable language was used in 1868 by Bovill, C.J., in his
judgment
in British Columbia Saw-Mill Co. v. Nettleship, L.R. 3
C.P. 490,
when (at page 505) he said:
" The
extent of carrier's liability is to be governed by the contract he
"
has entered into, and the obligations which the law imposes upon
him.
" He is not to be made liable for damages beyond what
may fairly be
" presumed to have been contemplated by the
parties at the time of
" entering into the contract. It must
be something which could have been
" foreseen and reasonably
expected, and to which he has assented
" expressly or
impliedly by entering into the contract."
In his
speech in the Monarch Steamship case (supra) Lord Porter
refers
(at page 214) to what " could reasonably have been
foreseen " and to what
" a shipowner ought to have
foreseen " as " likely to occur ". At page 215
he
spoke of what a shipowner " ought reasonably to have
contemplated ".
Lord Wright in the same case (at page 221)
refers to cases where " it would
" not be fair or
reasonable to hold the defendant responsible for losses which
"
he could not be taken to contemplate as likely to result from his
breach of
" contract". Lord Wright pointed out that the
Court will assume that the
parties, as business men, will have all
reasonable acquaintance with the
ordinary course of business, and
he spoke (see page 224) of what " reasonable
" business
men must be taken to have contemplated as the natural or probable
"
result if the contract was broken ". Lord Uthwatt in his speech
referred to
what a reasonable shipowner ought reasonably to have
foreseen: he would
in the circumstances of that case have regarded
the chance of war " not as
" a possibility of academic
interest to the venture, but as furnishing matter
" which
commercially ought to be taken into account ". Lord du Parcq
said
at page 233:
"
Damage arises ' according to the usual course of things' if, in the
"
circumstances existing at the date of the contract, both parties to
it,
" supposing them to have considered the probable effects
of a breach of
" the contract, with due regard to events
which might reasonably be
" expected to occur, must be
assumed as reasonable men to have foreseen
" such damage as
at least a serious possibility."
Furthermore,
in reference to the facts in that case, Lord du Parcq (at
page
233) said:
" In
order that the Respondents might succeed in establishing their
"
case, it was not necessary, in my opinion, that the parties to the
contract
" should be shown to have contemplated the outbreak
of war as something
" certain and unavoidable. They are not
to be supposed to have had
" the gift of prophecy. It is
enough if they may reasonably be assumed
" to have
contemplated a war, and the likelihood that it would lead
"
to such an embargo as was in fact imposed, as a real danger which
"
must be taken into account."
My Lords,
the words phrases and passages to which I have referred
are useful
and helpful indications of the application of the rule in Hadley
v.
Baxendale. But they neither add to the rule nor do
they modify it. I regard
the illuminating judgment of the Court of
Appeal in Victoria Laundry
(Windsor) Ltd. v. Newman
Industries Ltd. [1949] 2 K.B. 528 as a most
valuable analysis
of the rule. It was there pointed out (at page 540) that
in order
to make a contract-breaker liable under what was called "either
"
rule " in Hadley v. Baxendale it is not necessary
that he should actually
have asked himself what loss is liable to
result from a breach but that
it suffices that if he had
considered the question he would as a reasonable
man have
concluded that the loss in question was liable to result. Nor
need
it be proved, in order to recover a particular loss, that upon a
given
state of knowledge he could, as a reasonable man, foresee
that a breach
must necessarily result in that loss. Certain
illustrative phrases are employed
in that case. They are valuable
by way of exposition but for my part I
12
doubt
whether the phrase " on the cards " has a sufficiently
clear meaning
or possesses such a comparable shade of meaning as
to qualify it to take its
place with the various other phrases
which line up as expositions of the rule.
If the problem in the
present case is that of relating accepted principle
to the facts
which have been found, I entertain no doubt that if at the time
of
their contract the parties had considered what the consequence would
be
if the arrival of the ship at Basrah was delayed they would
have contemplated
that some loss to the Respondents was likely or
was liable to result. The
Appellant at the time that he made his
contract must have known that if
in breach of contract his ship
did not arrive at Basrah when it ought to
arrive he would be
liable to pay damages. He would not know that a loss
to the
Respondents was certain or inevitable but he must, as a
reasonable
business man, have contemplated that the Respondents
would very likely
suffer loss, and that it would be or would be
likely to be a loss referable
to market price fluctuations at
Basrah. I cannot think that he should escape
liability by saying
that he would only be aware of a possibility of loss but
not of a
probability or certainty of it. He might have used any one of
many
phrases. He might have said that a loss would be likely: or
that a loss
would not be unlikely: or that a loss was liable to
result: or that the risk
that delay would cause loss to the
Respondents was a serious possibility:
or that there would be a
real danger of a loss: or that the risk of his being
liable to
have to pay for the loss was one that he ought commercially to
take
into account. As a practical business man he would not have paused
to
reflect on the possible nuances of meaning of any one of these
phrases.
Nor would he have sent for a dictionary.
The
carriage of sugar from the Black Sea to Iraqui ports (including
Basrah)
is a recognised trade. The Appellant knew that there was a
sugar market at
Basrah. When he contracted with the Respondents to
carry their sugar to
Basrah, though he did not know what were the
actual plans of the
Respondent, he had all the information to
enable him to appreciate that a
delay in arrival might in the
ordinary course of things result in their suffering
some loss. He
must have known that the price in a market may fluctuate.
He must
have known that if a price goes down someone whose goods are
late
in arrival may be caused loss.
Since in
awarding damages the aim is to award a sum which as nearly
as
possible will put the injured party into the position in which he
would
have been if the breach of contract had not caused him loss
and if in all
the circumstances he had acted reasonably in an
effort to mitigate his loss,
I think that it must follow
that, where there is delay in arrival, in many
cases the actual
loss suffered (above the amount of which there ought not
to be
recovery) can be measured by comparing the market price of the
goods
at the date when they should have arrived and the market
price when they
did arrive. That prima facie is the measure
of the damages.
I can see
no fault, therefore, in the assessment of the damages in the
present
case unless there is some rule of law that in the case of carriage
of
goods by sea damages for delay in arrival will ordinarily be
limited to
interest on the value of goods over the period of their
delay. It is said
that such a rule underlies the decision in The
Parana L.R. 2 PD 118. In
reference to the suggestion that
there is a special rule limiting damages for
delay in delivery in
the case of carriage of goods by sea Lord Porter in
his speech in
the Monarch Steamship case (supra) said at page 219:
" No
doubt expressions of opinions to that effect are to be found,
"
perhaps more frequently in the days of sailing ships when prolonged
"
delay was to be expected, but it never was a rule of law—merely
a
" working practice answering to the circumstances of the
time and subject
" to the consideration that the contract
must be reasonably performed."
The
Parana (which was decided in 1877) was a case in which, owing to
the
weakness and defective state of her engines, a ship took 127
days on a
voyage from Manilla and Ilo-Ilo to London for which a
period of 65 or
70 days was said to be a fair average time. As a
result an assignee of bills of
lading of certain goods on the ship
claimed to recover damages resulting
13
from
unreasonable delay in the carriage of goods. The owner of the
ship
admitted liability and what was in issue was the amount of
the damages.
As to one portion of the cargo damages were given for
a deterioration in
quality due to delay. As to another portion of
the cargo the claim was
for the difference between the market
price at the time when the goods
arrived and at the time when they
ought to have arrived. As to that part
of the claim the Registrar,
who was directed to report upon the amount of
damages, considered
that the Court should refuse to entertain any claim
for loss of
market in such cases. In his report (see The Parana L.R. 1
P.D.
452) he said that the practice of the Court of Admiralty
should be followed
which was merely to allow a sum representing
loss of interest for the period
of delay on the capital value of
the cargo. One reason given was that the
loss of market "could
not by any possibility have been within the con-
" temptation
of the parties " when the cargo was put on board at Manilla.
He
appeared to think that a fall in the price of the goods could not
have
been in the contemplation of the parties when the contract
was made because
for aught they knew the price might have risen.
On appeal,
in objection to the report of the Registrar, it was held by
Sir
Robert Phillimore that the registrar ought to have included in
the damages
the difference between the market price of the cargo
at the time when it was
delivered and at the time when it ought to
have been delivered. He said
at page 464): —
" Why
should not the ascertained difference between the market price
"
when the goods might have been sold, had there been no delay, and
"
the market price which they would fetch after the delay, be a
reason-
" able measure of the loss of the merchant's profits?
The depreciation is
" the direct consequence of the carrier's
default; in other words, he
" must be taken to have known or
contemplated that the merchant desired
" a safe and a quick
transport of his marketable goods to their intended
"
market."
On
appeal to the Court of Appeal L.R. 2 PD 118 the judgment
was
reversed though the principle was accepted that if
circumstances are known
to the carrier from which the object of
the sender ought in reason to be
inferred so that the object may
be taken to have been within the contempla-
tion of both parties
damages may be recovered for the natural consequences
of the
failure of that object. Mellish LJ. in his judgment pointed to
differ-
ences between cases where there was delay by carriers on
land and cases
of " carriage of goods for a long distance by
sea ". , My Lords, I confess
that the differences do not seem
to me to be differences in principle. Mellish
L.J. considered that
there was an uncertainty as to whether the plaintiff was
affected
by the delay in arrival of the goods Pointing to the
circumstance
that the Plaintiff did not sell the goods on arrival
Mellish L.J. considered
that he might have acted in the same way
if the goods had arrived in time
—with the result that the
delay did not affect the plaintiff and to give him
damages would
be to give him speculative damages. So far as principle is
concerned
I prefer the judgment of Sir Robert Phillimore. It is to
be
remembered however that Mellish L.J. accepted as applicable to
carriage
of goods by sea both the language used in Simpson v.
London & North
Western Railway Co. 1 Q.B.D. 274, 277
(as cited by Sir Robert Phillimore)
and also the language of the
Lord Chief Baron in Home v. Midland Railway
Co. L.R. 8 C.P.
131 at page 137 The language used by the Lord Chief
Baron in
Horne's case was the language of Hadley v. Baxendale.
In prin-
ciple it seems to me that the rule in Hadley v.
Baxendale must in these days
be applied in cases of
carriage by goods by sea. If the parties for some
particular
reason have contracted on the basis that there is no obligation
to
proceed normally to a destination then delay would not
constitute a breach.
If, however, there is delay which amounts to
a breach of contract I see no
reason for adopting some special
formula in the assessment of damages (such
as giving interest on
the capital value of the goods carried) or for any
artificial
divergence from the principles that govern the
assessment of damages.
14
In The
Notting Hill L.R. 9 P.D. 105 which was decided in 1884, Hannen
J.
expressed disagreement with the decision in The Parana but
reluctantly
felt that he was bound by it. The Court of Appeal
agreed that it was an
authority binding on them Brett M.R. did not
wish to say that, had it
been for him to decide the case, he would
have decided it differently.
In Dunn
v. Bucknall Brothers [1902] 2 KB 614 it was known to
the
Defendants that the reason why the plaintiffs had shipped
goods (on the ship
of which the defendants were charterers) for
carriage to Algoa Bay was so
that the goods should be supplied to
British troops in South Africa and the
defendants knew that the
goods would sell at a much higher price if delivered
in due course
than if delivered at a later time when a large importation of
similar
goods would force prices down. For a breach of duty which resulted
in
the delayed arrival of the goods the defendants were held liable in
damages.
It was contended in the Court of Appeal that damages for
loss of market
are not recoverable in the case of delay in
carriage by sea and that a shipper
is only entitled to interest on
the value of the goods from the date when they
should have been
delivered down to the date of actual delivery. The con-
tention
was held to be ill-founded and Collins M.R. giving the judgment
of
the Court consisting of himself, Stirling L.J. and Cozens-Hardy
L.J. said that
they did not understand The Parana (supra)
as establishing any such general
proposition as that damages could
not be recovered for loss of market on a
voyage by sea. He said:
"
There can be no absolute peremptory rule taking voyages by sea
"
out of the principles which regulate the measure of damages on
"
breach of other contracts. It is only because the possible length
of
" voyages and the consequent uncertainty as to the times
of arrival
" may in many cases eliminate the supposition of
any reasonable
" expectation as to the state of the market at
the time of arrival that
" as a general rule damages for loss
of market by late delivery are not
" recoverable from the
carrier by sea. It is certainly not a rule of
" law, it is
only an inference of fact, that from the circumstances of
"
the case no reasonable assumption as to the state of the market
"
at the time of arrival could have been a factor in the contract
"
between the parties."
He
proceeded to point out that as the means of sea transit improved
then
voyages of three or four weeks duration could be accomplished
with
almost absolute certainty and furthermore that the state of
the market
at such reasonably calculated date of arrival could
well be " a vital factor
" present to the minds of both
parties at the time of making the contract".
He then added:
"
Wherever the circumstances admit of calculations as to the time
"
of arrival and the probable fluctuations of the market being made
with
" the same degree of reasonable certainty in the case of
a sea as
" of a land transit, there can be no reason why
damages for late delivery
" should not be calculated
according to the same principles in both
" cases."
On the
facts of that case it was known to the defendants that the
goods
would sell at a much higher price if duly delivered than if
tardily delivered
and the words I have quoted were uttered in that
context. I do not consider
however that where in breach of
contract there is delay in delivery, damages
will only be
recoverable if there can be a calculation in advance of the
precise
financial consequences that delay will cause. If there can be such
a
calculation then the carrier would know at the time of his contract
of
carriage exactly what the effect would be if by delaying
delivery he broke
his contract. But I cannot think that he should
be partially exonerated
merely by the circumstance that he could
not calculate in advance the extent
of the damage that he would
cause if he broke his contract. With the
knowledge possessed by
the Appellant in the present case, if. at the time
of the
contract, he had considered what the consequences would be if.
in
breach of contract, he delayed the delivery of the goods he was
carrying,
15
he must at
least have contemplated that there might well be market
fluctua-
tions as between the due date of delivery and the actual
date of delivery.
If by the actual date of delivery the market
price had advanced he might
be freed of any serious liability. But
he must have contemplated that
if the market went the other way he
would be causing loss. In running
the risk of causing that loss it
would not be reasonable to exonerate him
merely because in advance
the measure of the loss could not be calculated.
In R. &
H. Hall Limited v. W. H. Pim (Junior) & Co. Ltd. 33 Com.
Cas.
324 there was a failure by sellers to deliver goods to buyers:
there
had been a sub-sale by the buyers and then a further
sub-sale. The buyers
were held entitled to recover both their loss
of profit and also to recover
the damages that they would have to
pay to their sub-purchaser. It was
a case where the parties had
actually provided for the very case of sub-
sales. Non-performance
of the contract would therefore be known before-
hand by both
parties to be non-performance of a contract in which inter-
mediate
sales might take place. A question was raised as to whether
the
parties would have considered all the damage to be probable.
Lord
Shaw of Dunfermline said:
" To
what extent in a contract of goods for future delivery the
"
extent of damages is in contemplation of parties is always
extremely
" doubtful. The main business fact is that they are
thinking of the
" contract being performed and not of its
being not performed. But
" with regard to the latter if their
contract shows that there were
" instances or stages which
made ensuing losses or damage a not
" unlikely result of the
breach of the contract, then all such results
" must be
reckoned to be within not only the scope of the contract,
"
but the contemplation of parties as to its breach."
Further Lord Shaw said that he did not think—
"
that in such a contract people come to contemplate with any
"
exactitude the particular probable results which would follow from
"
a breach; say, that there would be a probable chance of re-selling
"
at a profit or that the chance of that would be even with their not
"
selling at a profit. What the parties to a contract such as this do
"
is not to estimate that the chances will be one way or the other or
"
will have this amount of probability or the other, but simply to
"
contemplate that trade chances are not unlikely to occur, and to
make
" a contract to cover such chances if any."
In the
same case Lord Phillimore referred to damages " which
naturally
" flow " from a breach of contract and to
damages which " the law super-
" adds in appropriate
cases " being " those damages which, though they
"
do not always or even usually flow from the breach of contract, are,
at
" the time of making the contract, recognised by the
parties as those which
" in a particular case may result from
a breach ". He added:
"
These are called damages in the contemplation of the parties, not
"
because the parties contemplate a breach of contract, but because
"
they recognise that a breach is possible, and they reckon that
these
" damages may flow from that breach. I designedly use
the word
" ' may'. There may be cases where the word to be
used might be
" ' will', but there are also cases and more
common cases where the
" word to use is ' may '."
Though
that case was one in which the parties had made express pro-
visions
in regard to sub-sales with the result that they must have "
recog-
" nised " that a purchaser might have to pay
damages to his sub-purchaser
if the vendor failed to deliver, the
expressions used in the speeches
illustrate that damages could be
recoverable in respect of a loss which
might occur or which the
parties could contemplate as not unlikely to
occur. The present
case is one in which no special information was given
to the
carrier as to what the Respondents intended to do with the
goods
after they arrived at Basrah. In those circumstances in
deciding what
damages would fairly and reasonably be regarded as
arising if the delivery
16
of the
goods was delayed I think that the reasonable contemplation of
a
reasonable shipowner at the time of the making of the charter
party must
be considered. I think that such a shipowner must
reasonably have con-
templated that if he delivered the sugar at
Basrah some nine or ten days
later than he could and should have
delivered it then a loss by reason of
a fall in the market price
of sugar at Basrah was one that was liable
to result or at least
was not unlikely to result. This results from the facts
of this
case. It is a question of what the parties contemplated. Even
without
notice of special circumstances or special considerations
there may be
situations where it is plain that there was a common
contemplation. In his
dissenting judgment in The Arpad [1934]
P. 189 Scrutton L.J. (at page 203)
said:
" I
am inclined to think that in contracts of carriage from wheat-
"
producing districts, it is always so probable that the shipper is
sending
" for resale, or for sale to a person who will
resell, that the carrier will
" be liable if there is no
market, for the effect on a contract of sale of
" his
conversion or unjustifiable failure to deliver."
Whether
this be so or not the Appellant in the present case must at least
have
appreciated that the Respondents wanted to have the goods at
Basrah at the
date when they should have been delivered there.
What could clearly be
foreseen was that the Respondents would be
without their goods at the place
where, and on the date when, they
were entitled to expect to have them.
Had there not been delivery
at all the damages would have been measured
by relation to the
market price of the goods at the date when they should
have been
delivered. In such an eventuality the Respondents would have
been
entitled to acquire goods to replace those which, either by reason
of
their having been lost or for some other reason, were not
delivered. By a
parity of reasoning since the parties had not
contracted on the basis that
the Appellant could deliver as and
when he liked but on the basis that he
should proceed at all
convenient speed and so should deliver on the date
that could with
reasonable accuracy be predicted, the Respondents would be
entitled,
if it were necessary, to acquire goods to replace those which had
not
arrived. If when the goods later arrived the market price had
advanced
the Respondents would suffer no loss: if the market price
had declined they
would suffer loss. If they actually suffered
loss it would prima facie be
measured as the difference
between the market price at the date when the
goods should have
been delivered and the market price at the date when
they were
delivered.
I would dismiss the appeal.
Lord Hodson
MY LORDS,
The broad
question which arises on the appeal is what is the correct
measure
of damages for wrongful delay by a shipowner in the performance
of
a contract for the carriage of goods by sea.
The
Respondents contend that the ordinary measure of damages for delay
in
delivery of goods for which there is a market is the difference
between
the market value of the goods at their destination on the
date when they
arrive, and the value at the date when they should
have arrived if there
had been no breach of contract. The loss so
measured is one which arises
naturally according to the usual
course of things. This right to recover does
not depend on any
special knowledge of the party in breach. It applies to
contracts
of carriage by sea and by land in all ordinary cases.
The
Appellant contends, on the other hand, that except in special
circum-
stances, which are not to be found in this case, the
measure of damages
is limited to the interest on the value of the
goods during the period of delay.
In these
circumstances the Appellant admitted liability for £172
consisting
of £12 10s. Od. (cable expenses) and £159
9s. 6d. (interest at 6 per cent, per
17
annum on
the full value of the cargo during the period of the delay) upon
the
facts found and stated in the Special Case.
The Umpire
awarded the charterers, in addition to the above sum of £172,
£4010
16s. 8d. in respect of the fall in value of the goods during the
delay.
McNair J. on questions of law being submitted for the
decision of the Court
as to (inter alia) the correct
measure of damages held that the Umpire was
wrong in law and that
the Respondents were entitled only to the admitted
sum of £172,
made up in the main of interest charges.
The Court
of Appeal, Diplock and Salmon, LJJ. (Sellers LJ. dissenting)
restored
the Umpire's award.
The
ultimate question for decision is whether, as a matter of law,
contracts
for the carriage of goods by sea are in a special class,
having regard to the
intrinsic differences there are between such
contracts and contracts for the
carriage of goods by land. For
example, in the former class, it is pointed
out that goods may be
sold before shipment or during the voyage or intended
for the
purposes of stocking or consumption at the port of destination
and
that the contemplation of the parties that the goods may be
resold by the
charterer at the port of destination is not
necessarily to be inferred. In
addition it is urged that ocean
voyages are liable to be affected by weather,
by congestion at
loading and discharging ports and similar factors which
account
for a different treatment being given to cases of carriage of
goods
by sea.
There is
on the face of it no reason why the charterer should not be
entitled
to the value of that of which he has been deprived by the breach
of
contract independently of his intention to sell again and sale
during the
voyage or before the shipment is in any case irrelevant
since the purchaser
would stand in the charterer's shoes. There is
nothing speculative about the
claim and what the charterer does
with the goods should not make any
difference. This should apply
to contracts of carriage by land or sea.
Consideration
of sea and weather conditions has been thought to be the
basis of
the decision in The Parana (1877) 2 P.D. 118. This appears
from
the judgment of Sir Richard Henn Collins M.R. in Dunn and
Others v.
Bucknall Brothers [1902] 2 KB 614. The
uncertainties of The Parana's
voyage were so great, said
the Master of the Rolls in Dunn v. Bucknall, that
the
parties could not be said to have contracted on the footing that the
goods
would arrive at any particular moment. The headnote to Dunn
v. Bucknall,
however, concisely states as a summary of
the judgment that there is no rule
of law that damages cannot be
recovered for loss of market on a contract
of carriage by sea.
This, I think, was really accepted by the Appellant
and also in
the main by McNair J. although Sellers L.J. went so far as to
say
that it was desirable in establishing a basis for damages to
avoid
fortuitous elements unless the parties have already
contracted that the
chance change of market price should fall on
the shipowner if it happened
to be less and not equal to or more
than the price which could have been
obtained without a breach of
contract.
That was
in substance the position taken up by the Appellant before
your
Lordships. He accepted the established authority of the judgment
in
Hadley v. Baxendale (1854) 9 Ex 341. The case
concerned a broken crank
shaft delivered to common carriers to be
sent to engineers for repair. There
was a delay of five days in
delivery and the issue was as to the measure of
damages for breach
of contract. In the judgment of the Court, which
consisted of
Barons Parke, Martin and Alderson, at page 354 it was said:
" We
think the proper rule in such a case as the present is this:
"
Where two parties have made a contract which one of them has
broken,
" the damages which the other party ought to receive
in respect of such
" breach of contract should be such as may
fairly and reasonably be
" considered either arising
naturally, i.e., according to the usual course
" of things,
from such breach of contract itself, or such as may be
"
reasonably be supposed to be in the contemplation of both parties, at
18
" the time they made the contract, as the probable result of the breach
" of it."
The
phrases beginning "either" and "or" are commonly
said to divide
the rule laid down by the Court into two parts, the
one arising " according
" to the usual course of things
" and the other relating to special circumstances
in which
the contract was made.
The
Appellant argued that the fluctuations of market due to
unforeseen
and unpredictable causes during the period of delay is
not of itself " according
" to the usual course of
things". He argued that there were no facts here
to bring the
second part of the rule into operation, and in this I agree with
him,
for no special notice was given. Hence he said that damages for
loss
of market are not recoverable and that these damages could
only be
recovered in special cases covered by the second part of
the rule.
The word "
probable " in Hadley v. Baxendale covers both
parts of the
rule and it is of vital importance in applying the
rule to consider what the
court meant by using this word in its
context. The common use of this word
is no doubt to imply that
something is more likely to happen than not. In
conversation, if
one says to another." If you go out in this weather you will
"
probably catch a cold " this is, I think, equivalent to saying
that you believe
there is an odds on chance that the other will
catch a cold.
The word "
probable" need not, however, bear this narrow meaning.
In
R. & H. Hall Limited v. W. H. Pim (Junior) & Company
Limited (1928)
33 Com. Cas. 324, Lord Dunedin, after stating
his belief in a general
agreement that the law as to calculation
of damages, due under breach of a
contract, was settled by the
case of Hadley v. Baxendale, said that the
difficulty
lies in the application to the facts of each case.
The
instant case furnishes an example of this difficulty. Assistance is
to
be gained from some of the expressions used in Hall v.
Pim which concerned
a loss of profit on resale. On failure
by sellers to deliver goods to buyers,
the buyers were held
entitled to recover the damages they would have to pay
to a
sub-purchaser. Lord Dunedin thought it was enough that there was
an
even chance of a resale happening. Lord Shaw thought it not
unlikely that
a resale would take place and Lord Phillimore that
the parties contemplated
that a resale may take place.
In the
Monarch Steamship Co, Ltd. v. Karlshamns Oljefabriker (AB)
1949
A.C. 196 Lord Du Parcq used in applying the first part of
the rule in Hadley
v. Baxendale the words "
serious possibility " and " real danger " while
Lord
Morton of Henryton spoke of " grave risk ".
A close
study of the rule was made by the Court of Appeal in the case
of
the Victoria Laundry (Windsor) Ltd. v. Newman Industries
Ltd.; Coulson
& Co. Ltd. (Third Parties) [1949] 2 K.B.
528. The judgment of the Court,
consisting of Tucker, Asquith and
Singleton, L.JJ., was delivered by
Asquith L.J., who referred to
the Monarch Steamship case (supra) and
suggested the phrase
" liable to result" as appropriate to describe the
degree
of probability required. This may be a colourless
expression but I do not find
it possible to improve on it. If the
word " likelihood " is used it may convey
the impression
that the chances are all in favour of the thing happening, an
idea
which I would reject.
I find
guidance in the use of the expression " in the great multitude
of
cases" which is to be found in more than one place in the
judgment in
Hadley v. Baxendale and indicates that
the damages recoverable for breach
of contract are such as flow
naturally in most cases from the breach, whether
under ordinary
circumstances or from special circumstances due to the
knowledge
either in the possession of or communicated to the defendants.
This
expression throws light on the whole field of damages for breach
of
contract and points to a different approach from that taken in
tort cases.
True that
where the facts are the same in two cases the damages will no
doubt
be the same whether the claim is made in contract or in tort;
compare
The Notting Hill (1884) 9 PD 105 where although
the claim was in tort
the Court of Appeal in a case like The
Parana followed the later decision.
19
The
approach in tort will, however, normally be different simply
because
the relationship of the parties is different. The claim
against the tortfeasor
who has inflicted tortious damage is not
the same as the claim against an
opposite party for breach of
contract for the latter claim depends on the
contemplation of the
parties to the contract and questions of remoteness as
such do not
arise. Consequently liability in tort may often be of a wider
kind.
The observations of Willes, J. in Home v. Midland Railway
Co.
L.R. 7 C.P. 583 at page 590 state the distinction in clear
language in the
passage cited by my noble and learned friend Lord
Reid and I agree that
this passage is to be preferred to the
opinion sometimes expressed that the
measure of damages is the
same in tort as it is in contract.
It seems
that Mellish, L.J. in The Parana (supra) took a different
view
of the rule in Hadley v. Baxendale when he
said:
" In
order that damages may be recovered, we must come to two
"
conclusions—first, that it was reasonably certain that the
goods would
" not be sold until they did arrive ; and,
secondly, that it was reasonably
" certain that they would be
sold immediately after they arrived, and
" that that was
known to the carrier at the time when the bills of lading
"
were signed."
With
respect to the Lord Justice this is putting the test too high. The
con-
clusion reached on the facts of the case in The Parana
need not however
be criticised because the voyage took about
twice as long as might have been
expected and no reasonably
accurate prediction of the length of the voyage
could be expected.
He did, however, make use of the general observations
which have
no doubt been treated as laying down a practice to be followed.
In
reaching the conclusion that the Registrar and merchants were
right
in their report he stated:
"
They said that it had never been the practice in the Court of
"
Admiralty to give such damages, and though it constantly happened
"
that by accidents such as collisions goods were delayed in their
arrival,
" it never had been the custom to include in the
damages the loss of
" market; and we are of opinion that the
conclusion which the Registrar
" and merchants came to was
right."
This
decision has been treated as authoritative by text writers in
this
country and has never been over-ruled but the rule of
practice which it
purports to lay down is not followed universally
and is insecurely based.
In the
United States of America it seems that the Courts have never
followed
the principle of assessment of damages laid down in The
Parana.
Salmon, L.J. has pointed out that in the Corpus Juris
Secundum, Vol. 80,
para. 124, it is stated that "In the
ordinary case of deviation or delay, the
measure of damages is the
difference in the market value of the goods at
the time when
actually delivered and when they should have been delivered."
In the
case of the United States v. Middleton et al. (1924) 3
F (2d) 384 and
in other cases in the United States of America this
position has been accepted.
It would,
I think, be unfortunate if the law as to the measure of damages
based
on the decision in Hadley v Baxendale in the two
countries should
be held to have developed on different lines and
I am glad to find that in my
opinion it has not in truth done so.
I have not
dealt in detail with the facts of the instant case. These have
been
sufficiently set out in the opinion of my noble and learned friend
Lord
Reid. I need only say that I agree with the majority of the
Court of Appeal
that, on the correct application of the decision
in Hadley v. Baxendale to the
facts stated in the
Special Case, although no special circumstances bring the
second
rule in Hadley v. Baxendale into operation, the
Appellant is liable
in damages for breach of contract in the
larger sum awarded, viz.
£4,188 10s. 8d., a sum which
includes damages for loss of market which in
this case arise "
according to the ordinary course of things ".
I do not
find it necessary to say that the decision in The Parana was
wrong
on the facts. Somehow or other from the language used in the
judgment it
20
appears to
have been elevated to a pronouncement on legal principle which is
not
sustainable.
Lastly
there is, in my opinion, no need to enter into the difficult
question
Whether there may be differences between cases of
non-delivery by carriers
and cases of delay by them. Certain
decisions upon this topic have been
criticised and I express no
opinion about them.
I would dismiss the appeal.
Lord Pearce
MY LORDS,
In Hadley
v. Baxendale the Court attempted to clarify and define
the
boundaries of damages in contract. In the Wagon Mound
[1961] AC 388
the Privy Council attempted a similar task with
regard to damages in tort.
In the present case (as in the Wagon
Mound No. 2 (reported as Overseas
Tankship (U.K.), Ltd. v.
Miller Steamship Co. Pty. Ltd. [1966] 2 All. E.R.
709)) it
was suggested in argument that there was or should be one principle
of
damages for both contract and tort and that guidance for one
could be
obtained from the other. I do not find such a comparison
helpful. In the
case of contract two parties, usually with some
knowledge of one another,
deliberately undertake mutual duties.
They have the opportunity to define
clearly in respect of what
they shall and shall not be liable. The law has
to say what shall
be the boundaries of their liability where this is not ex-
pressed,
defining that boundary in relation to what has been expressed
and
implied In tort two persons, usually unknown to one another,
find that the
acts or utterances of one have collided with the
rights of the other, and the
Court has to define what is the
liability for the ensuing damage, whether
it shall be shared, and
how far it extends. If one tries to find a concept of
damages
which will fit both these different problems there is a danger
of
distorting the rules to accommodate one or the other and of
producing a rule
that is satisfactory for neither. The problems
certainly have one thing in
common. In both the use of words with
differing shades of meaning in the
various cases makes it hard to
discern with exactitude where the boundaries
lie. See Wagon
Mound No. 2 [1966] 2 All ER 709 at 713.
The
underlying rule of the common law is that " where a party
sustains a
" loss by means of a breach of contract he is, so
far as money can do it, to
" be placed in the same situation
with regard to damages as if the contract
" had been
performed " (Baron Parke in Robinson v. Harmon 1
Ex. 850).
But since so wide a principle might be too harsh on a
contract-breaker in
making him liable for a chain of unforeseen
and fortuitous circumstances,
the law limited the liability in
ways which crystallised in the rule in Hadley
v. Baxendale.
This was designed as a direction to juries but it has become
an
integral part of the law.
Since an
Olympian cloud shrouded any doubts, difficulties and
border-line
troubles that might arise in the jury room and the
jury could use a common
sense liberality in applying the rule to
the facts, the rule worked admirably
as a general guidance for
deciding facts. But when the lucubrations of
judges who have to
give reasons superseded the reticence of juries, there
were
certain matters which needed clarification. That service was well
per-
formed by the judgment of the Court of Appeal in the case of
the Victoria
Laundry (Windsor) Ltd. [1949] 2 K.B. 528. I do
not think that there was
anything startling or novel about it. In
my opinion it represented (in felici-
tous language) the
approximate view of Hadley v. Baxendale taken by
many
judges in trying ordinary cases of breach of contract.
It is
argued that it was an erroneous departure from Hadley v.
Baxendale
in that it allowed damages where the loss was "a
serious possibility" or
" a real danger " instead
of maintaining that the loss must be " probable ", in
the
sense that it was more likely to result than not. But, over twenty
years
21
before, in
Hall v. Pim (1927) 33 Com. Cas. 324. Lord Dunedin had
said
(at 330) that it was enough if there was an even chance of
the loss happening.
Lord Shaw (at 334) said that the two parts of
the rule need not be anti-
thetically treated but might run into
each other and be one; and (at 335)
he read probable as meaning a
"not unlikely" result. Lord Phillimore
(at 336) said:
"
[They] are called damages in contemplation of the parties, not
"
because the parties contemplate a breach of contract, but because
"
they recognise that a breach is possible, and they reckon that
these
" damages may flow from that breach. I designedly use
the word
" ' may'. There may be cases where the word to be
used might be
" ' will', but there are also cases, and more
common cases, where the
" word to use is ' may'."
Lord
Blanesburgh expressed agreement with the others, and presumably
did
not dissent from the views set out above. Lord Haldane (at 327)
dealt
with the matter as one of construction: " Whether such
a resale was likely
" or not does not matter if, as I think,
the buyers stipulated for power to
" make it being provided."
I believe
that even at that date those observations would not be regarded
as
novel. And the fact that the case was not included in the Law
Reports
may be some slight confirmation of this belief. Inevitably
there is some
evolution of thought in such matters, and such as
there was tended in the
direction of taking a wider view of
probability. In 1948 in The Monarch
Steamship Co., Ltd. [1949] AC 196, a case of damages for delay in
carriage by sea. Lord Du
Parcq (at 233) used the words " at least a serious
"
possibility" and " a real danger which must be taken into
account."
Lord Uthwatt (at 232) spoke of " the chance of
war, not as a possibility
" of academic interest . . . but as
furnishing matter which commercially
" ought to be taken into
account." And Lord Morton of Henry ton spoke
of " a
grave risk " (235).
Accordingly
in my opinion the expressions used in the Victoria Laundry
case
were right. I do not however accept the colloquialism " on the
cards "
as being a useful test because I am not sure just
what nuance it has either
in my own personal vocabulary or in that
of others. I suspect that it owes
its attraction, like many other
colloquialisms, to the fact that one may
utter it without having
the trouble of really thinking out with precision what
one means
oneself or what others will understand by it, a spurious
attraction
which in general makes colloquialism unsuitable for
definition, though it is
often useful at shorthand for a
collection of definable ideas. It was in this
latter convenient
sense that the judgment uses the ambiguous words " liable
"
to result". They were not intended as a further or different
test from
" serious possibility " or " real danger
".
The whole
rule in Hadley v. Baxendale limits damages to that
which may
be regarded as being within the contemplation of the
parties. The first
part deals with those things that " may
fairly and reasonably be considered
" as arising naturally,
i.e. according to the usual course of things ". Those
are
presumed to be within the contemplation of the parties. As
Lord
Wright said in the case of the Monarch Steamship [1949] AC 196 at 224:
" As
reasonable business men each must be taken to understand the
"
ordinary practices and exigencies of the other's trade or business.
"
That need not generally be the subject of special discussion or
"
communication ".
After referring to the Banco de Portugal case [1932] AC 452 he continued:
"
Both parties were tacitly taken to be acquainted sufficiently with
"
the general business position. The same is true in many cases of
"
complicated consequences flowing from an unanticipated breach of
"
contract, but the damages are not treated either as special or
remote
" if they flow from the normal business position of
the parties which
" the court assumes must be reasonably
known to them. It would not
22
" be
helpful to cite the familiar authorities which are numerous but
"
depend primarily upon the facts of each case."
Even the
first part of the rule however contains the necessity for the
know-
ledge of certain basic facts e.g. in Hadley v.
Baxendale the fact that it was
a mill shaft to be carried.
On this limited basis of knowledge the horizon
of contemplation is
confined to things " arising naturally, i.e. according to
"
the usual course of things ".
Additional
or " special" knowledge, however, may extend the horizon
to
include losses that are outside the natural course of events.
And of course
the extension of the horizon need not always
increase the damages ; it
might introduce a knowledge of
particular circumstances e.g. a subcontract,
which show that the
plaintiff would in fact suffer less damage than a more
limited
view of the circumstances might lead one to expect. According
to
whether one categorises a fact as basic knowledge or special
knowledge
the case may come under the first part of the rule or
the second. For that
reason there is sometimes difference of
opinion as to which is the part
which governs a particular case
and it may be that both parts govern it.
I do not
think that Baron Alderson was directing his mind to whether
something
resulting in the natural course of events was an odds-on chance
or
not. A thing may be a natural (or even an obvious) result even
though
the odds are against it. Suppose a contractor was employed
to repair the
ceiling of one of the Law Courts and did it so
negligently that it collapsed
on the heads of those in Court. I
should be inclined to think that any
tribunal (including the
learned Baron himself) would have found as a fact
that the damage
arose " naturally i.e. according to the usual course of
"
things". Yet if one takes into account the nights, week ends,
and
vacations, when the ceiling might have collapsed, the odds
against it
collapsing on top of anybody's head are nearly ten to
one. I do not believe
that this aspect of the matter was fully
considered and worked out in the
judgment. He was thinking of
causation and type of consequence rather
than of odds. The
language of the judgment in the Victoria Laundry case
was a
justifiable and valuable clarification of the principles which
Hadley
v. Baxendale was intending to express. Even
if it went further than that,
it was in my opinion right.
Nor do I
consider that the Victoria Laundry case is inconsistent with
the
actual decision on the facts in Hadley v. Baxendale.
The carriers were asked
(without special directions, as the
Court found) to transport a broken shaft
away from a mill. "
In the great multitude of cases " (to quote the learned
Baron's
own phrase)—one would not expect the whole working of a mill
to
be stopped by a delay in transportation. The mere absence of
urgent
instructions spoke strongly against such a contingency. The
fact that the
shaft was to be used immediately by engineers for
measurements (which one
would have rather expected to go on paper
by post) for making a new shaft
would not, I think, have been in
the contemplation of the carriers, on the
meagre information
available.
The facts
of the present case lead to the view that the loss of market
arose
naturaly, i.e. according to the usual course of things, from
the shipowner's
deviation. The sugar was being exported to Basrah
where, as the
Respondents knew, there was a sugar market. It was
sold on arrival and
fetched a lower price than it would have done
had it arrived on time. The
fall in market price was not due to
any unusual or unpredictable factor.
Had this
been a case of non-delivery on sale of goods whether by sea or
land
it is uncontested that the defendants would be liable for the loss
of
market. Had it been a case of delay in sale of goods the prima
facie rule
is that the damage is the difference between "
the value of the article con-
" tracted for at the time when
it ought to have been and the time when it
" actually was
delivered " (per Blackburn J. Elbinger Actien-Gesellschafft
v.
Armstrong L.R. 9 Q.B. 473 at 477. Nor can it really
be contended that it
would have been otherwise if this had been a
case of delayed delivery in
carriage by land. For this has been
long established by such cases as
23
Collard
v. South Eastern Railway Company 158 E.R. 400; Wilson
v.
Lancashire and Yorkshire Railway Company 142 E.R.
248; and Horne v.
Midland Railway Company 7 C.P. 583
; 8 C.P. 131.
It is
however argued that different considerations arise in delay in
carriage
at sea. The decision in The Parana 2 P.D. 118, it
is said, established a
special principle or practice with regard
to delay in carriage by sea which
should apply to this case and
should confine the damages to loss of interest
on the value of the
goods. The Court of Appeal in The Parana appeared
to decide
largely on the ground that it was not " reasonably certain "
that
the goods would not be sold until they arrived and that they
would be sold
as soon as they did arrive. The estimates of the
duration of the voyage
appear to have varied between 65 days and
90 days; and in fact it took
127 days. And no doubt the chief
factor which influenced the Court was
that " the
uncertainties of the voyage were so great that the parties could
"
not be said to have contracted on the footing that the goods would
arrive
" at any particular moment". Sir Richard Henn
Collins M.R. said this
when he dealt with The Parana in
Dunn v. Bucknall Bros. [19021 2 K.B.
614 at 623. He
pointed out that " It is certainly not a rule of law but an
"
inference of fact that from the circumstances of the case no
reasonable
" assumption as to the state of the market at the
time of arrival could have
" been a factor in the contract
between the parties ". In the latter case the
Court did award
damages for loss of market. So too in The Ardennes [1951]
1
K.B. 55).
In the
United States the Corpus Juris Secundum states that " In the
"
ordinary case of deviation or delay, the measure of damages is the
"
difference in the market value of the goods at the time when
actually
" delivered and when they should have been
delivered, with interest". In
1924 in Middleton's case (3
Fed. Rep. 2nd Series 384 at 393) His Honour
Judge Rose of the
Federal Court of Appeals said:
" The
Parana was decided 47 years ago. It is by no means certain
that,
" even in England, it would now be unhesitatingly
followed. . . .
" Nearly half a century has elapsed since the
decision of The Parana and
" more than two decades
since that of Dunn v. Bucknall Bros. In the
"
meanwhile steam has more and more taken the place of the shift-
"
ing winds as the motive power upon the sea, with the result that
the
" duration of voyages may now be calculated with at least
some approach
" to certainty, even when they are to the ends
of the earth. In these
" days merchants make their
calculations accordingly, and it is not
" unreasonable to
insist that shipowners shall do the like. There would
" seem
to be little injustice in so doing, when it is remembered that they
"
are not answerable at all when they are able to show that the delay
"
was caused by something which due diligence on their part was
"
powerless to prevent."
In The
Parana (and in the present case) reliance was placed on the
fact
that in cases of carriage by sea the goods are likely to have
been sold in
transit while still afloat and that therefore the
shippers would not suffer by
their late arrival. But, if they were
so sold, under the bill of lading the buyer
would stand in the
shoes of the shipper, would suffer the loss, and would
sue in
respect of it. This fact makes the contemplation of the loss
neither
more nor less likely.
In my
opinion the line of approach in Dunn v. Bucknall Bros, and
in the
United States cases is correct. In most cases the loss of
market will be found
to be within the contemplation of the parties
in carriage of goods by sea.
It is however ultimately a question
of fact. And it may be that in some
unusual cases it will be found
that the situation between the parties showed
that the shipper was
indifferent to the time of arrival and that the parties did
not
contract on the basis that in case of deviation or delay the
shipowner
should be liable for loss of market. But the absence of
an express clause
(which could easily be inserted) to that effect
will obviously make it hard to
establish. I have not dealt with
the various particular facts in this case by
24
which Mr.
Kerr's able argument seeks to show that these particular parties
did
not contemplate damage by loss of market. For I agree with the
remarks
of the majority of the Court of Appeal on this subject.
Accordingly
if The Parana purported to lay down any general proposition
or
rule of law, it was wrongly decided. Even if it was merely
purporting
to draw an inference of facts from the particular case,
I have some doubt of
its correctness even at that date, and it has
no applicability to-day. And in
my opinion The Notting Hill 9
P.D. 105 which applied The Parana to a case
of tort, was
wrongly decided.
I would dismiss the appeal.
Lord Upjohn
MY LORDS,
This
appeal is concerned solely with the proper measure of damages for
an
admitted breach of contract by a shipowner resulting in the late
delivery
of a cargo which he contracted to deliver to the port of
discharge. The
practical question is whether the charterer can
claim damages for loss of
market as the cargo of sugar was to be
delivered to a port where there is a
market in that commodity.
The
general principle upon which damages are assessed for breach
of
contract is succinctly stated by Baron Parke in Robinson v.
Harmon 1 Ex. 850
at page 855—" Where a party
sustains a loss by reason of a breach of
" contract he is, so
far as money can do it, to be placed in the same situation
"
with respect to damages as if the contract had been performed ",
a statement
approved in your Lordships' House in Watts, Watts &
Co. Ltd. v. Mitsui
& Co. Ltd. [1917] A.C. 227 at
241. The same rule has been laid down in
your Lordships' House for
the assessment of damages generally including
torts (see
Livingstone v. Rawyards Coal Co. 5 A.C. 25 at page 39.
Such
general principles were, however, applied rather strictly for
until
Hadley v. Baxendale 9 Ex. 341, decided in
1854, the rule was that the damage
resulting must be the proximate
damage: thus in Smeed v. Foord (1 El. &
El. 602)
during argument when Hadley v. Baxendale was under
discussion
Campbell, C.J. interjected at page 608—" The
old rule was that, in estimating
" damages, only the
proximate injury sustained could be looked to ". With
the
increasing complications of life and the upsurge of industrial
activities
these simple rules failed to give sufficient guidance
to juries or indeed judges
for the assessment of damages for
breach of contract in more complicated
cases. But when Messrs.
Hadley, owners of a flour mill in Gloucester,
having sent a broken
mill shaft by the well-known carriers Pickfords to their
suppliers
in Greenwich to provide a pattern for a new shaft and there being
a
delay in delivery by Pickfords amounting to a breach of contract,
claimed
damages on the footing that the whole activities of their
mill were held up
for want of the shaft, it was clear that the
rule, though requiring some
expansion, must nevertheless receive
some limitation. This led to the famous
statement of Alderson B.
in that case 9 Ex. 341 at page 354.
" Now
we think the proper rule in such a case as the present is this: —
"
Where two parties have made a contract which one of them has
"
broken, the damages which the other party ought to receive in
respect
" of such breach of contract should be such as may
fairly and reason-
" ably be considered either arising
naturally, i.e., according to the usual
" course of things,
from such breach of contract itself, or such as may
"
reasonably be supposed to have been in the contemplation of both
"
parties, at the time they made the contract, as the probable result
of
" the breach of it. . . . "
Though
stated by the learned Baron in one sentence it contains and
has
always been interpreted as containing two branches and for my
part I .care
not whether it is regarded as stating two rules or
two branches of one rule,
though I prefer the latter. Thus:
25
Damages
should be such as may naturally and usually arise from
the
breach, or
Damages
should be such as in the special circumstances of the case
known
to both parties may be reasonably supposed to have been
in the
contemplation of the parties, as the result of a breach, assum-
ing
the parties to have applied their minds to the contingency of
there
being such a breach.
See
Hammond and Co. v. Bussey 20 Q.B.D. 79 approved in this House
in
R. & Hall Ltd. v. W. H. Pim (Junior) & Co.,
Ltd. 33 Com. Cas. 324. How-
ever there is no dichotomy between
these branches for as Lord Shaw pointed
out in the last-mentioned
case at page 334 " they may run into each other
" and
indeed be one ".
In British
Columbia & Vancouver Island Spar, Lumber & Saw-Mill Co.
Ltd.
v. Nettleship L.R. 3 C.P. 499 it was decided on the second
branch of
the rule that there must not only be common knowledge of
some special
circumstances but liability for damages resulting
therefrom must be made
a term of the contract. This was followed
in Home v. Midland Railway Co.
L.R. 8 C.P. 131. I do
not see why that should be so. If parties enter
into the contract
with knowledge of some special circumstances, and it is
reasonable
to infer a particular loss as a result of those circumstances that
is
something which both must contemplate as a result of a breach. It
is
quite unnecessary that it should be a term of the contract. I
agree with the
learned editor of the Third Edition of Halsbury
Vol. 11 page 243 note (m)
that those authorities ought not to be
followed. In any event, as Diplock
L.J. has pointed out, this
point had little application in practice.
So the
claim for damages must be the natural consequence of the breach
or
in the contemplation of both parties. But in tort a different test
has
been adopted in expanding the basic law of damages and I
cannot accept
the argument addressed to your Lordships that they
remain the same. The
test in tort, as now developed in the
authorities, is that the tortfeasor is
liable for any damage which
he can reasonably foresee may happen as a
result of the breach
however unlikely it may be, unless it can be brushed
aside as far
fetched. See the Wagon Mound cases [1961] AC 388 ; [1966]
3
W.L.R. 498.
This
difference is very reasonable. Once an examination of the
facts
establishes a breach of duty on the part of the tortfeasor,
the acts and
omissions of the innocent party are irrelevant until
the question of con-
tributory negligence comes to be considered.
A tortfeasor may and frequently
is a complete stranger to the
innocent party but he is, however fleetingly
in many cases, his
neighbour for the purposes of the law and bound to act
with due
regard to his neighbour's rights whoever he may be. If he fails
in
such duty the law has rightly laid down a more stringent test for
the
assessment of damages. But in contract the parties have only
to consider
the consequences of a breach to the other; it is fair
that the assessment
of damages should depend on their assumed
common knowledge and con-
templation and not on a foreseeable but
most unlikely consequence. The
parties may moreover agree to limit
or exclude liability for damage, or
agree on a liquidated sum, or
one party can disclose to the other special
circumstances which
will render a breach especially serious to him. So the
rules as to
the assessment of damages have diverged in the two cases,
and
nowadays the concept of " foreseeability" and "
contemplation of the
" parties " are different concepts
in the law. It is true that as a matter of
language there will in
many cases be no great difference between foreseeing
the
possibility of an event happening and contemplating the possibility
of that
event happening and in some of the cases, from Lord
Blackburn in Cory v.
Thames Ironworks L.R. 3 Q.B. 181 at
188 onwards the word foresee or
foreseeable is used in connection
with contract but it is clear that it has really
been used in the
sense of reasonable contemplation and in my view it is
better to
use contemplate or contemplation in the case of contract,
leaving
foresee or foreseeability to the realm of torts.
26
The rule
in Hadley v. Baxendale was approved in express terms in
Bank
of Portugal v. Waterlow [1932] AC 452 and in
The Monarch Steamship
Co., Ltd. v. Karlshamns Oljefabriken
(A/B) [1949] A.C. 196, and has been
followed in a
multitude of cases ever since it was decided. I think that apart
from
some very early criticisms it would be true to say that it stood
without
question until the case of Victoria Laundry (Windsor)
Ltd. v. Newman
Industries Ltd. [1949] 2 K.B. 528 when
it received a colourful interpretation
from Asquith L.J.
delivering the judgment of the Court.
My Lords,
in my opinion this appeal renders it necessary to determine
the
following questions:
(1) Has
the Victoria Laundry case purported to alter the law and
estab-
lish a somewhat different rule from that laid down in
Hadley v.
Baxendale for the assessment of damages in
contract;
(2) What,
as a practical matter, is the test to be applied in
ascertaining
whether any particular consequences of a breach of
contract should
lead to recoverable damages as arising either
naturally or such as
may have been within the contemplation of the
parties in the special
circumstances of the case ;
(3) Applying
that test, what on the facts of this case is the proper
measure of
damages ; unless
(4) Is
there some special rule of practice in relation to carriage of
goods
by sea established by The Parana [1877] 2 P.D. 118
which
precludes the recovery of damages beyond interest on the
value of
the goods over the period of the delay, unless the
plaintiff can bring
the case on its special circumstances within
the second branch of
the rule.
(1) Upon
the first point it is, I think, clear that on a fair reading of
the
judgments of the majority of the Court of Appeal they
considered that the
Victoria Laundry case did alter the
law. That case was one plainly within
the second branch of the
rule, but nevertheless the observations of Asquith
L.J. were in
general terms applicable to both branches. I do not myself
think
that the learned Lord Justice intended to alter the law. He was
para-
phrasing it and putting it into modern language, and I shall
refer to this
under the next heading. If he was doing more, I
would disagree with him.
But for my part I prefer to state the
broad rule as follows:
What was in the assumed contemplation of both parties acting as
reasonable men in the light of the general or special facts (as the case
may be) known to both parties in regard to damages as the result
of a breach of contract;
I omit for
the moment any adjectival qualification of the result which I
deal
with in (2) below Lord Wright pointed out in The Monarch
(supra) at 224
that each must be taken to understand the
ordinary practices and exigencies
of the other's trade but it must
be remembered when dealing with the case
of a carrier of goods by
land, sea or air, he is not carrying on the same trade
as the
consignor of the goods and his knowledge of the practices and
exigencies
of the other's trade may be limited and less than
between buyer and seller of
goods who probably know far more about
one another's business.
(2) Upon
the second point, what as a practical matter is to be taken as
within
the contemplation of both parties as the result of a breach?
The
words " probable result" held the field at first;
they were used in the
enunciation of the rule itself and by Esher
M.R. in Hammond v. Bussey
(supra) and adopted by
Lord Dunedin in Hall v. Pim (supra) at 330
who,
however, was careful to add that " probable " in
his view did not mean more
than an even chance. Lord Shaw in
that case interpreted the word probable
in the sense of the not
unlikely result (page 334). In The Monarch their
Lordships
used a variety of different expressions. I will very briefly
enumerate
them,—likelihood ; possibility must have been in
the minds of both parties;
a matter commercially to be taken into
account; a serious possibility or a
real danger ; a grave risk.
27
Asquith
LJ. in Victoria Laundry (supra) used the words " likely
to result"
and he treated that as synonymous with a serious
possibility or a real danger.
He went on to equate that with the
expression "on the cards" but like
all your Lordships I
deprecate the use of that phrase which is far too im-
precise and
to my mind is capable of denoting a most improbable and
unlikely
event, such as winning a prize or a premium bond on any
given drawing.
But in my
opinion Asquith L.J. was not attempting to do more than explain
the
rule in the light of the observations made in this House in The
Monarch.
It is curious that Hall v. Pim seems to
have escaped citation in all the later
cases until this appeal to
your Lordships
It is
clear that on the one hand the test of foreseeability as laid down
in
the case of tort is not the test for breach of contract; nor on
the other hand
must the loser establish that the loss was a near
certainty or an odds-on
probability. I am content to adopt as the
test a "real danger" or a
" serious possibility ".
There may be a shade of difference between these
two phrases but
the assessment of damages is not an exact science and what
to one
judge or jury will appear a real danger may appear to another
judge
or jury to be a serious possibility. I do not think that the
application of
that test would have led to a different result in
Hadley v. Baxendale. I
cannot see why Pickfords in
the absence of express mention should have con-
templated as a
real danger or serious possibility that work at the factory
would
be brought to a halt while the shaft was away.
(3)
Applying this test to the facts of this case the first and most
important
matter for consideration is the contract contained in
the Charter Party which
was dated 15th October, 1960. It provided
that the Heron II should pro-
ceed to Constanza and there load
3,000 tons of sugar and then proceed with
all convenient speed to
Basrah. At the date of the contract the ship was
dry-docked in
Piraeus and was expected to be ready to load about 25/27th
October,
so it was provided that lay days were not to run before then. It
was
further provided that if the ship was not ready to load by 10th
November,
1960, the charterers were to have the option to cancel
the Charter Party.
The charterers were also given the option of
discharging the cargo at Jeddah
to be declared 5 days before the
commencement of loading. The distance
from Constanza to Basrah is
4,370 miles and a reasonably accurate predic-
tion of the length
of the voyage was 20 days. The Heron II arrived at
Constanza on
27th October duly loaded and sailed on 1st November, 1960.
Due to
a number of breaches of contract which I need not specify the
vessel
took 29 days to complete the voyage instead of the
predicted 20. The ship-
owner knew of the existence of a sugar
market at Basrah but had no detailed
knowledge thereof. Those in
essence are the relevant facts upon which the
question of damages
has to be determined. It is common ground that the
question falls
within the first branch of the rule in Hadley v. Baxendale.
Both
McNair J. in the Court of first instance and Sellers L.J. in his
dis-
senting judgment in the Court of Appeal were impressed by the
fact that the
ship might lawfully have presented itself for
loading at any time up to
10th November and might have been
directed to go to Jeddah and this cir-
cumstance influenced each
of them in reaching the conclusion that loss of
market due to
delay could not have been within the contemplation of the
parties.
I cannot agree with this; Diplock and Salmon L.JJ., have, in
my
opinion, answered this point. The cancellation clause was put
in to protect
the charterer from undue delay if the repairs to the
ship in dry-dock should
take longer than anticipated ; its
existence does nothing in my opinion to alter
the common
contemplation of the parties as to the consequences of a failure
of
the ship to carry out the primary obligation to proceed on its
journey with
all convenient speed ; if anything it supports the
view that time was an
important element in the voyage. Nor can I
see the relevance of the fact
in this respect that another port of
discharge might have been designated.
It was not and the Heron II
was under contract to carry with all convenient
speed one cargo to
one port of discharge where there was a market for that
cargo.
28
This case
is quite different from those cases where cargo ships used
in the
old days literally to tramp up and down, for example, the
Mediter-
ranean, with liberty to call at any port in any order
(though that phrase,
as the authorities show, must receive a
limited and not a literal con-
struction) collecting and
discharging cargo as they steamed from port to
port; so that delay
in carrying a cargo to a particular port within a particular
time
or even with all convenient speed cannot have been within the
con-
templation of the parties as giving rise to damage for loss
of market—
see, for example, Connolly Shaw, Ltd. v. A/S
Det Nordenfjeldske D/S
49 LI. L. Rep. 183 at page 191 per
Branson J. The Ardennes 84 LI. L. Rep.
340 might have been
such a case if the facts had not brought it clearly within
the
second branch of the rule.
It has
long been established that in carrying marketable goods by rail
to
a place where there is a market it must be assumed to be in the
contem-
plation of the parties as a grave danger that the goods
may be sold on arrival
so that if there is a delay one of the
consequences may be loss of market.
See Collard v. South
Eastern Railway Company 7 H. & N. 79 and Home
v.
Midland Railway (supra). The plaintiff failed in the last case
because
there was no market loss and he failed to communicate the
circumstances
which led to his special loss. Is there any reason
why this rule should not
in principle apply to carriage of goods
by sea?
As long
ago as 1902 in the case of Dunn v. Bucknall Brothers [1902]
2
K.B. 614 Collins M.R. pointed out that sea voyages of three to
four
weeks duration are accomplished with almost absolute
certainty and the
state of the market may well be a vital fact
present to the minds of both
parties at the time of making the
contract.
In Jensen
v. Hollis Bros. & Co., Ltd. 54 L1. L. Rep. 133 Branson
J. at
page 137 did not over-exaggerate when he said that ships
with modern
facilities run with somewhat of the regularity of
railway trains. So I see no
reason why in principle the normal
rule as to carriage of goods by land
should not apply to the type
of voyage undertaken by the Heron II. I do not
refer to the
authorities to which your Lordships were referred where there
is a
complete loss of, or some physical damage to, goods such as
Rodocanachi
v. Milburn 18 QBD 67, for though the same
general principles apply,
both Lord Dunedin and Lord Atkinson
pointed out in Williams v. Agius
[1914] AC 510, that
there are substantial differences in practice between
late
delivery and non-delivery. Where marketable goods are lost it
is
almost axiomatic that the market price measures the damage ;
the same
cannot be said of delay ; it all depends on
circumstances. Different con-
siderations apply to cases between
buyer and seller, as I have already
pointed out. Nor do I think it
necessary to discuss Wertheim v. Chicoutimi
Pulp Co.
[1911] AC 301 and the criticisms of Scrutton L.J. of that
case
in Slater v. Hoyle & Smith [1920] 2 K.B. 11
; that controversy was really
concerned with the measure of
damages on subsales.
But the
Heron II took very nearly fifty per cent more than the
reasonably
predicted time and for no other reason than her owner's
breaches of
contract.
It is
perfectly true that at the time of the contract nothing was said as
to
the purpose for which the charterer wanted the sugar delivered
at Basrah ;
he might have wanted to do so to stock up his supply
of sugar or to carry
out a contract already entered into which had
nothing to do with the market
at Basrah; or he might sell it
during the voyage, but all that is pure
speculation. It seems to
me that on the facts of this case the parties must
be assumed to
have contemplated that there would be a punctual delivery
to the
port of discharge and that port having a market in sugar there was
a
real danger that as a result of a delay in breach of contract the
charterer
would miss the market and would suffer loss accordingly.
It being estab-
lished that the goods were in fact destined for
the market the shipowner
is liable for that loss.
(4) I
turn, then, to the last question. Does The Parana (supra) lead
to the
conclusion that in the case of carriage of goods by sea
there is a different
29
rule of
practice; it is not suggested that there is any different rule of
law.
McNair J. and Sellers L.J. thought so and that damages were
limited to
loss of interest on the value of the goods detained.
No
doubt in the days of sail pure and simple, when ships might be
delayed
by head winds for days, loss of market would not be within
the contemplation
of the parties. In 1877, when The Parana was
decided, the steam engine
was coming into its own but it was still
the golden age of sail and over
half the ships built in this
country were sailing ships at this time; these
matters may well
have influenced Mellish L.J. when he pointed out the
difference
between delay in delivery by carriers on land and cases of
carriage
of goods on long voyages by sea. Perhaps he was right as matters
then
stood, but the rapid improvement in the steam engine led to a
different
statement of principle in Dunn v. Bucknall
Bros, (supra) a
statement in accordance with general principle and which must govern
the assessment of damages today. The Parana, which has only once been
followed in Notting
Hill 9 P.D. 105 and frequently criticised, must be regarded as
either
obsolete, being overtaken by events or as overruled. It may
be noted that
The Parana was not treated by Mellish LJ. as
a tramp steamer in the sense
in which I have used that phrase
earlier in this judgment.
In Dunn
v. Bucknall (supra) an explanation of the decision in
The
Parana was suggested, that the estimates of the proper
time for completion
of the voyage of the Parana varied very
greatly so that the time of arrival
was not predictable. This
explanation was not given by Mellish L.J.
himself and I doubt if
it is valid.
Even
today, when very long journeys half-way round the world are
under-
taken, the estimate of the time which a ship ought to take
may vary within
wide limits; see, for example, two cases in the
U.S.A., the United States v.
Middleton 3 Fed.
Reporter 2nd Series 384 (an Atlantic port to Japan
60 to 90 days)
and the Iossifoglu 32 Fed. Reporter 2nd Series 928
(Phillipines
to a U.S. Atlantic port 46 to 66 days). Nevertheless
in both those cases
it was held that in the case of marketable
commodities being carried to a
market, if the ship greatly exceeds
the larger estimate through breach of
contract and the cargo owner
thereby misses his market he is entitled to
damages for loss of
market. I agree with those decisions, so far as the
Judges who
decided those cases felt no difficulty by reason of the fact that
the
time of arrival could only be estimated within broad limits.
For these reasons I would dismiss this appeal.
(329304) Dd. 196999 100 10/67 St.S.